🎧 New: AI-Generated Podcasts Turn your study notes into engaging audio conversations. Learn more

Coping with Permanent Austerity PDF

Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...

Summary

The article examines the politics of reform in the welfare states of affluent democracies, specifically within a context of permanent austerity. It argues that welfare states are facing intense pressures, but support remains broadly widespread. The author discusses complications of social policy reform and configurations of welfare state politics.

Full Transcript

Coping with Permanent Austerity 411 The argument proceeds in three stages. In the first, I outline a basic frame-...

Coping with Permanent Austerity 411 The argument proceeds in three stages. In the first, I outline a basic frame- work for studying the politics of reform in a context of permanent austerity. 13 In the second, I discuss two complications: the need to incorporate different dimensions of social policy reform and the need to recognize three quite distinct configurations of welfare state politics among the afOuent.democra- Coping with Permanent Austerity cies. In the third, I apply these arguments to analyse the politics of restruc- turing in the liberal, social democratic, and conservative 'worlds' of welfare Welfare State Restructuring in Affluent Democracies capitalism. Paul Pierson 1. AN INITIAL FRAMEWORK FOR STUDYING THE POLITICS OF PERMANENT AUSTERITY' THE welfare states of the affluent democracies now stand at the centre of political discussion and social conflict. Analysts frequently portray these conflicts as fundamental struggles between supporters and opponents of Despite some disagreement concerning the main sources of pressure on the basic principles of the post-war social. contract. They often emphasize mature welfare states, the chapters in Part I all conclude that the welfare that the politics of social policy are played out against the backdrop of a state now faces a context of essentially permanent austerity. Changes in the transformed global economy that has undercut the social and economic global economy, the sharp slowdbwn in economic growth, the maturation of foundations of the welfare state. While containing elements of truth, such governmental commitments, hpd population ageing all generate consider- , portrayals distort crucial characteristics of the contemporary politics of able fiscal stress. There is little reason to expect these pressures to diminish the welfare state. Changes in the global economy are important, but it is over the next few 'decades. If anything, they are likely to intensify. primarily social and economic' transformations occurring within affluent Underlining the severe pressures confronting mature welfare states does democracies that produce pressures on mature welfare states. At the same not, however, imply that the expected result is a collapse or radical retrench- time, support for the welfare state remains widespread almost everywhere. ment of national welfare states. Major policy reform is a political profess, In most countries, there is little sign that the basic commitments to a mixed dependent on the mobilization of political resources sufficient to over- economy of welfare face a fundamental political challenge. Nor is there much come organized opponents and other barriers to change. The welfare state's evidence of convergence towards some neoliberal orthodoxy. opponents have found it very difficult to generate and sustain this kind of Yet the chapters in this volume have also stressed that welfare states are political Mobilization. undergoing quite significant changes. In this conclusion, I argue that the I have developed this argument elsewhere (Pierson 1994, 1996) and present contemporary politics of the welfare state take shape against a backdrop only a condensed version here. The sources of the welfare state's political of both intense pressures for austerity and enduring popularity. In this con- strength are diverse, but are of two basic types: the electoral incentives asso- text, even strong supporters of the welfare state may come to acknowledge ciated with programmes which retain broad and deep popular support and the the need for adjustment, and even severe critics may need to accept the institutional 'stickiness' which further constrains the possibilities for policy political realities of continuing popular enthusiasm for social provision. Thus, reform. Together, these features have created tremendous resilience in the face in most of the affluent democracies, the politics of social policy centre on of two decades of welfare state 'crisis' (Stephens, Huber, and Ray 1999). the renegotiation, restructuring, and modernization of the terms of the post- war social contract rather than its dismantling. The crucial issue is whether Electoral Incentives particular national settings facilitate the emergence of such a centrist reform effort, and if so, on what terms. In market democracies, voters play a crucial role. Implementing and sus-. taming policy reforms over time generally requires electoral vindication. Voters, Thanks to Andrew Karch and Effi Tomaras for research assistance. I have benefited from however, amain strongly attached to the welfare state. The broad public many conversations with participants in the New Politics project and the European Forum at the EUI. I owe special thanks to John Myles and Ann Orloff, although I suppose it would 1 be unfair to hold them responsible for the end result. This section draws on material presented in Pierson 1998. 412 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 413 45 r TABLE 13.1. Major welfare state clienteles in three countries, 1995 IS Sweden 40 - 35 - L Germany Sweden Germany United States J United States Pensions 1,584,304 21,630,000 43,388,000 30 - Disability 408,576 1,180,000 5,857,656 25 - Unemployment 37,734 1,990,000 7,900,000 Social assistance 474,159 2,080,000 4,869,000 20 Public welfare employment 1,245,800 1,590,000 2,540,000 15 TOTAL 3,750,573 28,470,000 64,554,656 Electorate 6,551,591 56,090,000 ; 196,089,000 10 Percentage 57.25 50.76 32.92 5 Sources: Sweden—Statistiska Centralbyran, Statistisk Arshok '97 (1997). Germany—Statistiches 0 1980 1950 1960 1970 Bundesamt, Statistiches Jahrbuch Jiir die Bundesrepublic Deutschland (1998). United States— Years Committee on Ways and Means, 1996 Green Book (1996). German welfare state clientele data and American electorate data cover 1996. Fro. 13.1. Welfare state clienteles as a percentage of the electorate, 1950-80 Sources: Welfare state clienteles include public social welfare employment (excluding education) as well as recipients of pensions, disability, social assistance, and unemployment benefits. All welfare state clientele date comes from tables 4.5, 4.16, 6.3, 6.10, 7.4, and 7.14 in Richard Rose. currently receive social benefits expect that they may at some point in their Public Employment in Western Nations (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985). lives. Or they may be in the same household with someone who receives bene- Electoral data comes from Thomas T. Mackie and Richard Rose, The International Almanac of Electoral History (London: Macmillan, 1991), fully revised, third edition. All American welfare fits from, or is employed by, the welfare state. In most countries, universal state data covers 1952, 1962, 1972, and 1982. American electoral data covers 1952, 1964, 1972, programmes, especially health care but also other social services, generate and 1984. German electoral data covers 1949, 1961, 1969, and 1980. Swedish electoral data widespread support. Furthermore, the welfare state retains considerable covers 1952, 1960, 1970, and 1979. legitimacy as a source of social stability and guarantor of basic rights of citizenship. Popular support generally appears to extend well beyond the support consistently reveaWd in polls stems from several sources. As the wel- confines of narrow economic self-interest. fare state has expanded, so has the size of its constituencies. As Peter Flora Support for the welfare state is intense as well as broad. Intensity of has noted, 'including recipients of [pensions,] unemployment benefits and preference matters because it is associated with higher rates of political social assistance and the persons employed in education, health and the social mobilization and with voters' actual choices at election time. The intensity 1 services, in many countries today almost /2 of the electorate receive transfer of support for the welfare state stems from two factors. First, while the bene- or work income from the welfare state' (Flora 1989: 154). Figure 13.1 and fits of retrenchment for welfare state opponents are generally diffuse and Table 13.1 offer a very rough indication of the political transformation asso- often uncertain, the large core constituencies for the welfare state have a con- ciated with welfare state expansion. Figure 13.1 shows the dramatic impact centrated interest in the maintenance of social provisiob. Huge segments of welfare state growth from roughly 1950 to 1980. It tracks a conservative of the electorates of advanced industrial societies rely on the welfare state measure of welfare state employment, plus a very conservative estimate of for a large share of their income. It is one of the few basic axioms of polit- transfer recipients, as a. share of the total electorate for three representative ical science that concentrated interests will generally be advantaged over countries. From the beginning of the post-war expansion (1960) to the rough diffuse ones. end of the maturation period (1980) these ratios increase markedly in all The second source of intensity stems from the fact that welfare state sup- cases. Table 13.1 provides snapshots from the mid-1990s for the same coun- porters are in the position of fighting to sustain already existing benefits. tries. Again measured on a conservative basis, one can see both that the core Students of electoral behaviour and political psychology have found that constituencies of the welfare state are very large, And that there are marked voters exhibit a 'negativity bias'—they react more intensely to potential losses variations across countries. than to commensurate potential gains. Thus, the welfare state's electoral These crude indicators considerably underestimate the scale of the wel- base is not pnly enormous, but primed to punish politicians for unpopular fare state's reach into contemporary political life. Many voters who do not initiatives. 414 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 415 in' previous decisions. As a result, as Douglass North has emphasized, change Institutional 'Stickiness in well-institutionalized polities is typically incremental. Those seeking policy reform must confront not only the potential opposition Research on technological change has revealed some of the circumstances of voters and programme beneficiaries but the stickiness of existing policy conducive to path dependence (David 1985; Arthur 1994). The crucial factor arrangements. By stickiness I have in mind two features of developed polities is the presence of increasing returns, which encourages actors to focus on that reinforce the electoral obstacles to radical reform: formal and informal a single alternative and to continue movement down a particular patkonce institutional 'veto points', and 'path dependent' processes, which in many initial steps are taken. Large set-up or fixed costs are likely to create increas- cases tend to lock existing policy arrangements into place. Each of these char- ing returns to further investment in a given technology, providing indi- acteristics pushes reform agendas in the direction of incremental adjustments Viduals with a strong incentive to identify and stick witla, a single option. to existing arrangements. Substantial learning effects connected to the operation of complex systems The basic point about veto points is straightforward and clearly spelled provide an additional source of increasing returns. Coordination effects (or out in Bonoli's contribution to this volume (see more broadly Scharpf 1986; network externalities) occur when the individual receives increased bene- Tsebelis 1995). Most political systems make policy reform dependent on more fits from a particular activity if others also adopt the same option. Finally, than a simple 51 per cent majority, allowing minorities (including in some adaptive expectations occur when individuals feel, a need to 'pick the right cases quite small ones) opportunities to block reforms. Examples of such horse' because options that fail to win broad acceptance will have draw- institutional arrangements include federalism, a strong judiciary, bicamer- backs later on. Under these conditions, individual expectations about usage alism, use of referenda, requirements of super-majorities, and coalition-based patterns may become self-fulfilling. governments.' Difficult as it is to create a majority coalition in favour of As North has argued, all of these arguments can be extended from restructuring the welfare state, even that may not be enough. The multiplica- studies of technological change to other social processes, particularly to the tion of veto points can hamstring efforts at policy change, frustrating even an development of institutions. In contexts of complex social interdependence, ambitious and aggressive reform coalition such as the Republican congres- new institutionsior policies often entail high fixed or start-up costs, may involve sional majority in the United States after 1994, or an enduring conservative considerable learning effects, and generate coordination effects and adapt- coalition such as the one governing Germany from 1982 to 1998. ive expectations. Established institutions generate powerful inducements that A second major source of stickiness, path dependence, is more complex. reinforce their own stability and further development. 'In short', North con- Because path dependence is often invoked as an explanation without fur- cludes, 'the interdependent web of an institutional matrix produces massive ther explication, some elaboration is necessary.' Certain courses of political increasing returns', making path dependence a common feature of institu- development, once initiated, are hard to reverse. It is not just that institu- tional evolution --(North 1990: 95). tional veto points may make a reversal of course difficult. Individual and Over time, as social actors make commitments based on existing institu- organizational adaptations to previous arrangements may also make reversal tions, the cost of 'exit' rises. Learning from past rents may lead actors to unattractive. act differently in launching new initiatives. Recapturing ground in previously Recent work on, path dependence has emphasized the ways in which initial institutionalized fields of activity, however, will often be quite difficult. social outcomes concerning institutional, organizational, or policy design Actors do not inherit a blank slate that they can remake at will when their even suboptimal ones—can become self-reinforcing over time (Krasner 1989; preferences change or the balance of power shifts. Instead, they find that North 1990). These initial choices encourage the emergence of elaborate the dead weight of previous institutional choices seriously limits their room social and economic networks, greatly increasing the cost of adopting once- to manoeuvre. possible alternatives and therefore inhibiting exit. Major social arrangements Because this point is so often misconstrued, it should be stressed that have major social consequences. Individuals make important commitments the claim is not that path dependence 'freezes' existing arrangements in in response to government actions. These commitments, in turn, may vastly place. Change continues, but it is bounded change. North (1990: 98-9) increase the disruption caused by institutional reforms, effectively 'locking- summarizes the key point well: 'At every step along the way there [are] choices—political and economic—that provide... real alternatives. Path 2Veto points may also be policy-specific. The Canada Pension Plan (CPP), for example, depende,nce is a way to narrow conceptually the choice set and link decision cannot be reformed without a large super-majority among provincial governments. See also the discussions in the chapters by Myles and Pierson and Wood. A more detailed making through time. It is not a story of inevitability in which the past discussion can be found in Pierson (2000). neatly predicts the future.' 416 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 417 One of the major themes of this volume is that contemporary welfare states, option. Continuing low growth coupled with the challenges of creating service and the politics that surround them, strongly reflect these path-dependent sector employment, population ageing, and the overcommitments of existing effect& As Myles and Pierson argue, old-age pension systems provide a power- policies are already generating intense pressures. Tax levels strain public ful example. Most countries operate pensions on a pay-as-you-go basis: tolerance. Payroll tax burdens and their possible adverse impact on employ- current workers pay 'contributions' that finance the previous generation's ment and wages create tensions within the traditional support coalitions of retirement. Once they have been in place for a long time, pay-as-you-go sys- the welfare state (Visser and Hemerijck 1997). Barring an extremely unlikely tems may face incremental cutbacks and adjustments, but they are highly return to an era of high economic growth, fiscal pressures on welfare _states resistant to radical reform. Shifting to private, funded arrangements would are certain to intensify. While tax increases may contribute to the place an untenable burden on current workers, requiring them to finance gap between commitments and resources, it is difficult to imagine that in the previous generation's retirement while simultaneously saving for their own. many European countries changes in revenues alone could be sufficient to Even partial privatization has generally proven possible only in the relatively maintain fiscal equilibrium. Thus, even strong supporters of the welfare state few countries lacking extensive and mature pay-as-you-go systems. increasingly acknowledge that sustaining basic arrangements will require Similar if less severe path-dependent effects are likely in areas of social significant reforms. It is a context of permanent austerity. policy where complex sets of institutions and organizations have 'co-evolved' The prospect of permanent austerity transforms political conflicts over the over extended periods. The chapters by Giaimo, Manow, and Wood all restructuring of social policy. Welfare state conflict is often portrayed as a emphasize this type of dynamic. In health care provision and many aspects clash between those wedded to the status quo and those eager to dismantle of labour market systems, social actors need to coordinate their activities and basic social protections._ In countries where aggressive advocates of neoliber- they invest resources in line with the incentive structures of their existing alism have been in power, such as New Zealand and until recently the United environment (see also Giaimo and Manow 1999; Hacker 1998). This prob- Kingdom, this has not been too inaccurate a portrayal. Yet in a climate where ably helps to explain why employers, for instance, have often been more half- social trends make pressures on budgets intense and unrelenting, political hearted and internally divided over policy reform than many theories of cleavages are likely to become more complex. Those, advocating restructur- political economy might have anticipated (Thelen 1999). ing will include many who wish to preserve and modernize key elements of Both the popularity of the welfare state and the prevalence of 'stickiness' the social contract, but seek to do so in a manner which does not create must be at the centre of an investigation of restructuring. The essential point unsustainable budgetary burdens, contributes to economic performance, is that welfare states face severe strains and they retain deep reservoirs of and gives emerging social demands some chance of competing for public political support.'For political analysts, the central question can thus be put attention and resources with well-established ones. In the current climate, as follows: What happens when the irresistible forces of post-industrialism__ restructuring must be distinguished from retrenchment or dismantling. meet the immovable object of the welfare state? Acknowledging the strength My central contention so far is that neither the alternatives of standing of both sides of this collision generates several implications for investigating pat or dismantling are likely to prove viable in most countries. Instead, as the politics of reform. in many aspects of politics, we should expect strong pressures to move towards There are strongthe grounds for scepticism about the prospect for any more centrist and therefore more incrementalist—responses. Those seek- radical revision of welfare state in most countries. Almost nowhere ing to generate significant cost reductions while modernizing particular aspects have politicians been able to assemble and sustain majority coalitionsfor a of social provision will generally hold the balance of political power. In Claus far ,reaching contraction of social policy (Stephens, Huber, and Ray 1999). Offe's words, the objective for those wielding electoral power in most coun- — The- reasons have already been outlined. The broad scale of public suppbrt, tries will be 'smooth consolidation' (Offe 1991). the intensity of preferences among programme recipients, the extent to which_ A useful initial framework for fleshing out this claim is a simple version a variety of actors (including employers) have adapted to the existing con- of the pivotal politics argument suggested in recent studies of American toilirTaf the social market economy, and the institutional arrangements which politics (Krehbiel 1998; Brady and Volden 1998). In any collective choice - - favour defenders of the status 061 riake a frontal assault oil the welfare state situation where policy preferences can be arrayed on a single continuum, politically suicidal in most countries. there is a pivotal actor whose vote determines whether an initiative moves Yet the chapters in Part I of this volume also suggest that pressures asso- forward or is blocked. This pivotal voter is likely to wield disproportionate ciated with post-industrialism, intensified in some respects by globalization, power, and policy outcomes should generally gravitate towards that loca- have rendered the maintenance of the status quo an increasingly unrealistic tion. Pivotal voters need not be median voters. A great deal turns on the 418 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 419 institutional environment governing choice. Depending on the significance Q of multiple vetoes and super-majoritarian systems, the pivotal voter will C V R generally be closer to the status quo than the median voter—often much FIG. 13.2. Identifying the viable space for policy reform. closer. In the United States, for instance, if a President is prepared to veto legislation, the pivotal voter in the legislature is not the one generating a Of course, students of comparative public policy have long recognized bare majority, but the one producing the two-thirds majority required for the role of positive-sum bargaining among crucial organized interests and a veto override. 4 political parties. In most advanced industrial democracies the new economic In practice, the political vulnerability of those seeking to modify popular and fiscalenvironthent has transformed, but not undermined the conditions social welfare programmes is such that they will often seek relatively broad for consensus-oriented policy making based on political exchange. What has consensus on reform rather than a `minimum winning coalition'. Broader changed is the 'currency' for such exchanges. Traditionally, labour's contribu- consensus legitimates the claim that policy change is necessary and intended tion to consensus was wage restraint. As Rhodes argues, even following the to sustain rather than gut the programme under review; it thus provides demise of Keynesianism this contribution remains important. Yet reformers essential political cover (Weaver 1986). The desire to make reform durable of the welfare state also require credibility and legitimacy, particularly in generally points in the same direction. Especially with large, complex, and the eyes of voters. Left and centre-left parties, and/or trade unions, gener- deeply institutionalized programmes like health care and pensions, social actors ally need to be brought into reform coalitions to Make the restructuring of place a high value on predictability and continuity in policy. Reform is not welfare states politically sustainable. enough; powerful interests seek reasonable assurance that the new policies The implications of the discussion so far can be seen in Figure 13.2. can be sustained. This again encourages the assembly of grand coalitions. Depicting policy reforms on a continuum from the status quo (q) to a full- Such coalitions, often informal and issue-specific, extend the range of actors fledged neoliberal agenda of radical retrenchment (r), one would expect the with a stake in the reform outcome, and increase confidence that the next median voter (m) to be a considerable distance from (r). The need to 1.1r- election will not overturn the new initiatives. mount institutional veto points pushes the government reform agenda back In other words, the pivotal actor in practice will generally be closer to the to (v), and the desire to gain legitimacy-enhancing and stability-inducing status quo than the actor identified by a formal analysis of the institutional consensus promotes a further move to (c). My argument is thus that in most preconditions for minimum winning coalitions. In a wide range of countries, of the affluent democracies the viable reform space will be, at a maximum, the coalitions engaged in the restructuring of welfare states have been far in the region (c)–(v). Reform thus entails a substantial shift from (q), but broader than minimum size, incorporating key interest organizations as well it is a long way from (r). as political parties outside the current government. Such a broadening pur- chases the increased legitimacy and potential durability of enacted reforms. Most often, the price is a more incremental adjustment than would have 2. TWO MAJOR COMPLICATIONS been (theoretically) possible with a smaller coalition. A final, related factor in pushing the 'pivot' towards the status quo is the possibility that the'governments capable of enacting reform at a limited polit- This is of course an extremely stylized treatment of reform politics. A more ical cost will be those possessing the greatest credibility with voters on the satisfying account would need to complicate the analysis in two crucial issue (F. Ross 1998). Following a 'Nixon goes to China' logic, it will often respects. First, one needs to develop a more nuanced conceptualization of the be those governments with reputations of support for the welfare state that reform agenda, or, in social science terms, the dependent variable. Second, have the greatest room to manoeuvre. Yet the very factors that produce such one needs to consider the distinctive reform dynamics of different welfare credibility (past commitments, ideological orientations, and the nature of a state regimes. Each of these complications represents an important part of party's core constituencies) make it unlikely that the favoured party will use the current agenda for research on the politics of the welfare state. its enhanced manoeuverability to dismantle established social policies. Again, political incentives point towards more moderate, modernizing reforms. Three Dimensions of Welfare State Restructuring 4More precisely, it is the voter producing a two-thirds majority in the chamber where that One of the'''striking features of current comparative research on the welfare voter's preferences are closest to the status quo. state is the lack of consensus on outcomes. How much, and in what ways, have 420 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 421 welfare states changed since the end of the post-war boom? The authors in concept cuts against our attempts to generate the relatively parsimonious this volume generally depict most reforms in most countries as incremental measures of outcomes that make a serious enterprise of comparative explana- rather than radical, and focused on restructuring rather than straightforward tion possible. dismantling. However, some have argued that the degree of cutbacks has A second problem stems from data limitations. Even if we agree about been more severe (Clayton and Pontusson 1998). Even among those who see the outcomes that we are interested in measuring, how do we carry out the the overall degree of change as fairly limited, there may be little agreement measurements? This problem has become more acute as—again for quite about how to characterize the nature and scope of change cross-nationally. good reasons—analysts have criticized simple efforts to characterize out- It is difficult to exaggerate the obstacle this dissensus creates for comparat- comes through indicators of public or social expenditure. Following Esping- ive research. As Kitschelt notes in his chapter, it is impossible to seriously Andersen's lead, there has been a broad recognition that many of the evaluate competing explanations when there is no agreement about the pat- theoretically relevant outcomes of welfare state change will simply not be tern of outcomes to be explained. Thus, it is important to ask why researchers captured by expenditure data. Indeed, I have argued elsewhere (Pierson 1994) have so much trouble with the dependent variable. that this is especially true in the current environment. There is every reason The problem lies partly in the concept of the welfare state itself, partly in to believe that policy makers will seek systematically to engineer changes that data limitations, and partly in limitations of current theorizing about welfare produce their major expenditure implications only at a later point in time. state change. 'The welfare state' is generally taken to cover those aspects of In short, there is probably no substitute for investigations that pay attention government policy designed to protect against particular risks shared by broad to fairly detailed dimensions of policy change, including attempts to map segments of society. Standard features, not necessarily present in all countries, their (perhaps uncertain) long-term implications. Rigorously applying con- would include: protection against loss of earnings due to unemployment, sistent criteria to even a small subset of the affluent democracies is a time-. sickness, disability, or old age; guaranteed access to health care; support for consuming and expertise-taxing enterprise. 5 Carrying out such research-Tor' households with many children or an absent parent, and a variety of social the affluent democracies as a whole would require the efforts of a large and services—child care, elder care, etc.—meant to assist households in balan- well-funded team.'So far no one has carried it out. 6 cing multiple activities which may overtax their own resources. The final element of the 'dependent variable' problem stems from limita- Needless to say, this list covers an extremely wide range of government tions of theory. It is this issue that I want to explore in more detail here. activity. Furthermore, the trend in scholarship has been to broaden the already One of the hidden premisses of much recent writing on the welfare state has extensive domain of the subject matter. Recent analyses have advocated more been a return to the simple dichotomy of 'more' vs. 'less'. Implicitly, change attention to public/private interplay (e.g. Shalev 1996; Howard 1997) and is measured along a single continuum, stretching from the intact (or even to the.interfaces between the public sector, the market, and the household expanding) welfare state on one end to the seriously eroded or dismantled (Orloff 1993; Esping-Andersen 1999; O'Connor, Orloff, and Shaver 1999). on the other. Yet here again Esping-Andersen's core insights retain force. In In this volume, Schwartz makes a similar appeal for extending attention to a context where actors have complex motives, and the dependent variable systems of social protection built into the regulatory arrangements govern- is so heterogeneous, attempts to reduce change to a single dimension will ing particular economic sectors. There is little doubt that this broadening be counterproductive. has had salutary effects; forcing attention to dimensions of social life that Instead, starting from the perspectives of prominent actors in the had,previously received scant attention, and illuminating the extent to which reform process, we can think about change along three dimensions: welfare states are nested in a set of broader institutional arrangements. re-commodification, cost containment, and recalibration. 7 Each constitutes Yet as the concept of the welfare state, or welfare regime, 'stretches', it be- a potentially important dimension of welfare state restructuring. Any effort comes inevitable that quite distinct processes and outcomes will be joined to focus on only one will necessarily distort what the process of restructuring together under the umbrella of a single master variable (Collier and Levitsky 1997). This in turn spreads confusion in two ways. First, it fuels a process Two excellent examples are Alber 1998b and Lindbom 1999. Alber covers three countries, where analysts discussing what has happened to 'the welfare state' find although he limits himself largely to transfer programmes. Lindbom covers one country. themselves talking past each other because each is concerned with distinct 6 The voluminous Scharpf/Schmidt project probably comes closest, but it does not attempt to systematically measure policy outcomes at the level of programmes across the countries dimensions. Second, it makes efforts to develop summary measures of what in their study* has happened extraordinarily difficult. The complexity of this multifaceted I am grateful to Jonathan Zeitlin for suggesting the term `recalibration'. r 422 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 423 is about. For any welfare state, or any particular weilare state programme, As Manow stresses in his chapter (see also the contributions of Rhodes, we can fruitfully think about the extent to which reform agendas and policy Swank, and Huber and Stephens) the attitude of private firms to the expan- outcomes involve change along each of these dimensions. sion of the welfare state cannot be reduced to one of recalcitrant opposi- tion to de-commodification. To argue that employers have been enthusiastic Re-commodcation builders of the welfare state would be revisionism run amok. Yet particular De-commodification, in Esping-Andersen's influential formulation, 'occurs elements have been enormously appealing to particular employer inter- when a service is rendered as a matter of right, and when a person can ests, facilitating rather than impeding their core strategies (Mares 1998). maintain a livelihood without reliance on the market' (1990: 21-2). For Moreover, in many other respects employers have adjusted to welfare state Esping-Andersen, the centrality of de-commodification stems from his earl- arrangements—and policy makers have accommodated the welfare state to ier reflections on the construction of the social democratic welfare regime employep—over extended periods of time. As Soskice (1999) has argued, (Esping-Andersen 1985). He argued that this regime was fashioned through particular types of firms are likely to thrive in particular institutional settings. the efforts of a highly mobilized and well-organized working class, which Thus, there is often a strong co-evolutionary aspect to the intersection between sought to use political power to overcome its vulnerabilities in the labour varieties of capitalism and systems of social provision. market. Re-comraodification essentially involves the effort to reverse that This is not to suggest that commodification has not been a relevant dimen- process to restrict the alternatives to participation in the labour market, sion in recent struggleS over the welfare state. For particular actors, in par- either by tightening eligibility or cutting benefits. ticular countries, with respect to particular programmes, this dimension has Particularly for those who see the current era as defined by the rise been highly salient. 'Work incentives' have been the focus of concern in many of business power, re-commodification stands as the key dimension for an cases, ranging from the reform of Dutch disability pensions to the abolition investigation of welfare state restructuring. The transformation of social pro- of AFDC in the United States. Yet there remains considerable variation vision, froM this perspective, is primarily about dismantling those aspects of in the extent to which welfare state reform has focused on improving work the welfare state that shelter workers from market pressures, forcing them incentives. All of the studies in Part IV emphasized that reform is often not to accept jobs on employers' terms. This formulation has proven particularly primarily about re-commodification. As Wood argues, even actors who one central to analyses. of welfare state reform produced by those who come might think would make this a high priority—e.g. German employers—have to the topic from previous work on industrial relations. For these scholars, often had more pressing concerns. The task for analysts then becomes three- the shifting balance of power between employers and unions stands at the fold: to identify the conditions under which a focus on re-commodification centre of political analysis (Clayton and Pontusson 1998; Swenson 1991b). is significant, to establish the degree of change along that dimension, and Re-commodification clearly represents an important dimension of wel- to explain the observed patterns. At the same time, one must avoid the fare state change. Yet it is increasingly evident that the basic logic of de- temptation to reduce the discussion of welfare state restructuring to this commodification outlined in Esping-Andersen's Three Worlds was at least single aspect. somewhat misleading even for the period of welfare state expansion dur- ing the post-war period.' It suggests an image of welfare states foisted. Cost Containment on capitalists. The problem with this line of thinking is not that it takes capitalism too seriously, but that it fails to take capitalism seriously enough. In his powerful critique of expenditure-based analysis of welfare state These are, after all, economies where investment depends on the capacity of variations, Esping-Andersen observed that spending levels were essentially capitalists to earn profits, and where the need to induce investment therefore derivative of, and often not a good proxy for, other outcomes (such as de- confers substantial political power (Lindblom 1977). The question thus arises: commodification, poverty relief, or status maintenance) which actors valued. How would programmes seriously damaging to economic performance thrive During the period of welfare state expansion, he argued pointedly, 'it is diffi- so extensively for so long? cult to imagine that anyone struggled for spending per se' (Esping-Andersen 1990: 21). 8As Ann Orloff has stressed to me, commodification's connotation of diminished auto- nomy or choice is also problematic when applied to women, for whom the shift from unpaid In the current climate, however, people do fight against spending per se. household work to participation in the paid labour market may enhance rather than diminish Indeed, this is a defining characteristic of the era of austerity. As I argued autonomy. in Chapter 3, a range of pressures, including the shift from' manufacturing 424 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 425 to services, demographic and household change, and the maturation of Recalibration governmental commitments are placing inexorable demands on government budgets. Deficit reduction is a high priority for many of the countries that Still, the agenda confronting contemporary welfare states cannot be reduced have joined or seek to join the European Monetary Union. In many con- to cost containment plus commodification. By recalibration I mean reforms texts, powerful actors are concerned first and foremost with the implications which seek to make contemporary welfare states more consistent with con- of reform for levels of government expenditure. Of course, the imposition temporary goals and demands for social provision. Two different types of of austerity may become a vehicle for the pursiiii of other ambitions, but recalibration should be distinguished. Rationalization involves the modifica- often the principal focus is cost containment itself. tion of programmes in line with new ideas about how to achieve established With the exception of Wilensky's important work (Wilensky 1981), social goals. Updating concerns efforts to adapt to changing societal demands scientists have generally treated social expenditure and taxation as two dis- and normg—e.g. changes hr the household, the life course; the nature of tinct realms of research. In reality, of course, they are two sides of the same the labour market, or the age composition of societies. Rationalization coin, inextricably linked. The'need to finance public spending in the current includes attempts to correct obviously 'incentive-incompatible programmes' environment often becomes the most powerful constraint on existing social or cases of overshoot which may become evident over time, especially if policy arrangements. Employers and financial interests worry about high tax external circumstances change in a way which greatly changes the function- levels because of their potential impact on profits—an impact that may be ing of programmes. Examples might include disability programmes in the felt through a number of distinct channels. In many countries, for instance, Netherlands, or public service pensions in France and Italy. This kind of a major preoccupation is the fear that high fixed labour costs, generated in modernization would also include reforms of service systems, including health part by payroll tax rates, are seriously impeding the ability of employers to care, designed to improve the efficiency of provision or the responsiveness hire low-skilled workers. of such systems to consumer needs and demands. Of course, the other political channel for opposition to taxes runs through The reform of Sickness Pay in Sweden can serve as an example of ration- the electorate. As the welfare state has expanded, its financial underpinnings alization. By the mid-1980s, absenteeism rates in Swedish workplaces began have shifted, necessarily, to heavy reliance on funds from middle-income to reach extremely high levels. There was fairly broad agreement that sick households. Higher taxes, combined with slower growth of real incomes, pay programmes were being abused—that these programmes were helping have generated popular discontent. In most countries, politicians must also to produce high rates of absence from work rather than, as intended, pro- cope with the downside of pay-as-you-go financing. As Myles and Pierson viding protection against an important social risk. Spending rose sharply, argue, the current era marks the reversal of the favourable political dynamic from under 2 per cent of GDP in the early 1980s to almost 3 per cent Of that accompanied the phase-in of pay-as-you-go pension systems. During GDP in 1988 (Benner, Vad, and Schludi 1999: graph 23). The result was the 'golden age' politiCians could make generous promises while deferring a consensus—partial and not without conflict—on a set of reforms to cor- the cost (i.e. high payroll tax rates). Today's politicians, rather than being rect these tendencies. Replacement rates were cut, and waiting' days added. in a position'to claim credit for new initiatives, act primarily as the bill- Revenue-neutral changes were introduced to increase the incentives of collectors for yesterday's promises. Although voters almost everywhere employers to monitor use of sick pay provisions. Both the pattern of reforms retain widespread allegiance to public social provision, these sentiments are and their timing suggest that the dominant concern was to restore sick pay now intermingled with stiff resistance to significant tax increases (Bonoli, to its originally intended role rather than to worsen the terms on which George, and Taylor-Gooby, forthcoming). genuinely sick workers could choose to be absent from work. Governments face the unenviable task of reconciling strong tendencies for This is tricky territory analytically. Since in the current context these reforms higher outlays with the potential for voter backlashes and the possibility will often be designed to save money, how do we distinguish the impact of that new taxes will damage economic performance. At the same time, new ideil about how to do things, or efforts to recalibrate errant programmes, most countries face tighter constraints on their ability to run deficits (most from simple cutbacks in provision? Yet clearly we do not want to smuggle obviously in countries subject to the convergence criteria of EMU). In this all modifications of programmes into a framework of 'assaults on the climate, cost containment itself emerges as a top priority. Again, the ques- welfare state'. Over time actors will sometimes discover that particular pro- tions for analysts are to identify the circumstances where a focus on cost grammes der not work as intended, or they will determine that there may containment becomes prominent, to establish the degree to which that goal be better ways of achieving their goals. In such a context, they will push is achieved, and to explain the patterns identified. for changes. Thus, recent reforms in Swedish health care provision have 426 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 427 produced considerable reorganization and resulted in public employment this volume's 'policy domain' chapters (Part IV). Wood sliows that in the reductions, particularly among the low-skilled. From one vantage point case of labour market reform the primary agendas are re-commodification (Clayton and Pontusson 1998) this represents a fundamental assault on and recalibration, in differing and quite interesting configurations. By con- public sector workers. From another, however, it represents an attempt to trast, cost containment is a much less significant motivation for policy reform. increase productivity in the public sector in order to provide high-quality An the case of health care and pensions, on the other hand, cost contain- and flexible services to consumers at a politically sustainable cost. The ment is the issue in most countries, though flanked in some cases by efforts equation of public sector reform with simple retrenchment or the roll-back at modernization. Only rarely will re-commodification provide the primary of the state is highly questionable without evidence that cost-savings have lens for analysing the character of reform in these core welfare state sectors. reduced service quality. To take a third example, in the case of family policies, the main pressure all Updating involves the modification of existing programmes, or the initi- welfare states face is the need to adapt social policy arrangements to the ation of new ones, in response to newly recognized social needs. A defining radically transformed interfaces between market, state, and households. characteristic of the current era is the coexistence of social conditions which Distinct dimensions of welfare state restructuring will be of varied salience are in many ways 'new' with welfare states which are in many respects not only across programme areas, but across countries and over time. For decidedly 'old' (Esping-Andersen 1999). As has been discussed, mature wel- instance, acute fiscal crises or the dash to meet EMU's convergence criteria fare states will tend to be characterized by various forms of stickiness. In obviously place a premium on cost-containment efforts. More generally, I will addition, many current policy outcomes are the lagged effects of decisions argue in the next section that the three different 'worlds' of contemporary taken decades ago. There is thus often a considerable 'mismatch'. between welfare capitalism give rise to distinct policy agendas and, in part as a result, emerging social risks and shared understandings of appropriate targets for distinct competing political coalitions and reform dynamics. It has been in state intervention, on the one hand, and the existing array of government the liberal welfare states that a focus on re-commodification has been most social, policies, on the other. The various aspects of this mismatch con- pronounced. These already highly commodified welfare states have become stitute an important dimension of restructuring agendas in contemporary more so—especially in Britain, New Zealand, and the United States. By welfare states. contrast, recalibration and cost containment have been more central to the Problematic as the concept of recalibration might be, it is more problematic policy agenda in Continental welfare states, while cost containment has been to reduce the nature of current welfare state restructuring to simple cost the principal issue in the social democratic welfare states of Scandinavia. containment plus re-commodification. A variety of initiatives, dealing with A focus on multiple reform dimensions thus , allows the analyst to highlight issues such as gender equity and social exclusion, simply cannot be squeezed the distinct problem loads of different welfare states. into these other categories. Consider some of the most striking initiatives of Finally, disaggregating these reform dimensions increases our capacity to recent years: the introduction of 'private' but essentially mandatory super- make sense of relevant political processes, facilitating more nuanced accounts annuation in Australia (C. Pierson 1998); the establishment of long-term care of actor interests and political activity. Different actors may be concerned insurance in Germany (Getting, Haug, and Hinrichs 1994); the enactment about distinct dimensions of reformuarticular actors may have multiple or expansion iri many countries of a range of subsidies or 'contribution but partly, conflicting objectives. Furthermore, because of these multiple credits' for unpaid caring work (Daly 1997); and the marked expansion of priorities /there may be unsuspected opportunities for issue-linkage and various initiatives to 'make work pay' by subsidizing the terms on which negotiated change in which different actors trade off lesser concerns for workers enter the low-paid labour market (Myles and Pierson 1997). None greater ones. As noted in the chapters by Bonoli, Rhodes, and Myles and of these initiatives can be incorporated into a simple vision of expanding Pierson, one of the striking observed outcomes in some configurations is markets (commodification) and contracting states (cost containment). unexpected coalitions based on quid pro quos. One can place this in the Introducing these three dimensions of welfare state restructuring confers framework outlined in the first part of this chapter. Recognizing the multi- several very considerable analytical advantages. First, breaking down the very dimensionality of reform is crucial in a context where many actors agree broad category of 'change' into discrete dimensions sharpens our capacity on the need for 'change' but have different interests and priorities. Analysts to discern distinct patterns in outcomes. One can identify striking variations elsewhere (Levy 1999; Myles and Pierson 1997) have stressed the centrality both across policy arenas and across countries. Particular sectors of the wel- of compromise and the search for positive-sum trade-offs under condi- fare state tend to be much more preoccupied with one or another dimen- tions where broad political coalitions are necessary and straightforward sion of welfare state restructuring. The differences are clearly highlighted in retrenchment is politically difficult to sell. r 428 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 429 qualitatively different configurations with distinctive historical roots'. Caus- Three Distinct Welfare State Regimes ally, the claim is that 'countries cluster on policy because they cluster on The second necessary complication of my initial framework stems from politics' (Shalev 1999: 13, emphasis in original). In this framework, it makes the need to recognize the existence of very distinct political and policy no sense to argue for a linear relationship between independent variables configurations--distinct regimes—within the ranks of the affluent demo- /and dependent variables, e.g. that 'any discrete increment of Catholicism or cracies. Up until now I have spoken of essentially a single 'logic' of welfare absolutism ought to yield a discrete and uniform increment in pension state reform. Just as we have to distinguish different reform dimensions, how- "corporativism" ' (ibid.)." ever, we also need to recognize the existence of quite different settings for The arguments about path dependence discussed earlier in this chapter the emerging politics of restructuring. 9 and elsewhere in this volume (Myles and Pierson, Wood), as well as the Esping-Andersen's typology of three worlds of welfare capitalism—liberal, contributions which focus on linkages among regime features (Manow, conservative, and social democratic—has been enormously influential. At Huber and Stephens) point in the same direction. Path-dependent processes the same time, it has been subjected to frequent criticisms, mostly stress- are very likely to be prevalent in contexts where a set of organizations and ing that particular countries are poorly categorized, or arguing that other institutions develop together over extended periods of time, reinforcing each dimensions of variation are neglected. Any typology covering the com- other through processes of mutual adaptation and competitive selection. plex realities of a large number of countries is vulnerable to this kind of Institutions and organizational actors that constitute a poor fit are less likely challenge. Yet there are excellent theoretical and methodological reasons to survive over time. Such processes foster the emergence of quite distinct to organize the explanation of variance in outcomes around an analysis configurations, containing many elements which 'make sense' in the context of distinct regimes rather than lumping all OECD countries into a single of the others. To take a prominent example (Huber and Stephens 1999) a pool in which one scrutinizes variance along a single, continuous range of number of factors operated together to create the 'Social Democratic service `independent' variables. state'. In particular, the rapid entry of women into the workforce, in a con- `To talk of a regime', Esping-Andersen maintains, 'is to denote the text marked by social democratic party and union strength, fuelled demand fact that in the relation between state and economy a complex of legal and for supportive social services. Efforts to meet that demand through public organizational features are systematically interwoven' (1990: 2). What was sector expansion both created additional opportunities for women's employ- most compelling in Esping-Andersen's analysis of modern welfare states ment and strengthened political forces pushing for further expansions. was his insistence that welfare states be seen as part of complex historical Different welfare state configurations are the products of complex con- configurations. 10 The 'three worlds' did not result from 'more' or 'less' of junctural causation, with multiple factors working together over extended a few discrete, independent master variables, but from the interactive and periods of time to generate dramatically different outcomes. There is no cumulative effects of a number of interdependent causal factors. 'Variables' theoretical justification for arguing that a 10 per cent shift in the value on may have a particular impact only when accompanied by a set of addi- one variable or another will have a simple, direct, linear effect On outcomes tional factors. This perspective has strong affinities with Ragin's concept across all cases. To clarify, let me discuss one example: the impact of political of `complex conjunctural causation' (Ragin 1987). As Shalev has put it, the institutioni. on the prospects for reform in the current period. Most discus- argument is that welfare regimes should be seen as 'a limited number of sion of this issue has addressed welfare states in genefal. Pierson and Weaver (1993) stressed that there was no clear theoretical basis for believing that 9 In case it is not obvious, I should acknowledge that many of the arguments in increased institutional fragmentation necessarily made retrenchment more Pierson '1994 and Pierson 1996, especially those which de-emphasize the contemporary role difficult. The concentration of authority also concentrated accountability, of organized labour, suffer from precisely this defect. This criticism is effectively advanced in Visser and Hemerijck 1997. 10 In this respect, the analysis runs directly parallel to a very prominent theme in com- " Esping-Andersen himself employed such regressions, but as Shalev argues persuasively, parative political economy, emphasizing the varieties of contemporary capitalism (Kitschelt there is an 'obvious mismatch between Esping-Andersen's claims and his methods... The et al. 1999b; Hall 1999; Soskice 1999). In Soskice's influential account, 'there are strong regression approach... treats both policy and politics as continuous variables.... It is hard interlocking cornpletnentarities between different parts of the institutional framework. Each to exaggerate the fundamental incompatibility between [multiple regression] and Esping- system depends on the other systems to function effectively' (1999: 109). Spurred in part by Andersen's regime approach.... In his hands [multiple regression] was simply a blunt Esping-Andersen's work, a number of researchers have begun to explore the connections between instrument lor tapping gross differences between groups of countries that could have been production systems and welfare state regimes (see Ebbinghaus and Manow 1998; Huber and conveyed by the use of tables and charts without the implication of constant linear effects Stephens, Manow, Rhodes, and Wood, in this volume). across countries' (Shalev 1999: 13). 430 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 431 which might lead to difficulties in pursuing unpopular policies. This Even if one accepts the basic case for treating cases holistically, as con- accountability/blame avoidance dynamic is important for understanding why figurations rather than compilations of variables, one can nonetheless chal- even unified governments will often be cautious, for explaining the strategies lenge Esping-Andersen's specification of regimes. A number of reasonable that such governments employ, and for highlighting the possibility that objections have appeared, and for particular purposes one might prefer a aggressive action may lead to electoral backlash. different typology. Yet I am struck by the extent to which other analysts, By now, however, the evidence would seem to show pretty clearly that on -including those studying broader shifts in political economy, have gravitated balance the concentration of political authority is an asset for those seek- towards similar demarcations (Iversen and Wren 1998; Kitschelt et al. 1999a; ing reform.' 2 As Huber and Stephens argue, the experiences of the two pure Scharpf 1997b). My view is that this reflects a reasonably tight fit between Westminster cases, New Zealand and the United Kingdom, are particularly particular welfare state configurations and particular political configurations. striking. New Zealand's National government was able to move aggressively This is indeed what one should expect if Esping-Andersen was correct in on multiple fronts. The British Conservatives gradually learned to shift from- arguir}g that each regime type emerges from a particular political milieu. a strategy of frontal assaults to one of relentless, low-profile adjustments, As 'Walter Korpi has argued, in evaluating the heuristic merits of typo- which whittled away important elements of the welfare state over time. By logies, 'the analysis of causes and consequences of welfare states shduld be contrast, veto points in other countries have generated significant, sometimes in the foreground' (Korpi 1999: 35). Ultimately, the crucial issue is whether overwhelming, obstacles to radical change. the distinction among regimes provides leverage for explaining important Yet it is no accident that both these examples of major retrenchment variations across the relevant cases. In Section 3 of this essay, I argue that it in the absence of formal institutional veto points concern liberal welfare states, does—although not always in the manner suggested by Esping-Andersen's where social actors are disorganized and popular support for the welfare own discussions. When combined with the disaggregation of reform dimen- state is (while still extensive) more limited than elsewhere. It seems highly sions outlined above, one can begin to make sense of variations both across unlikely that the same 'value' on this particular independent variable would regimes and among cases within each regime. have similar consequences in a configuration where popular 'support for the welfare state was broader and/or the power resources of labour were greater —a conclusion which Bonoli's discussion of the French reform experience 3. RESTRUCTURING THE THREE 4,k supports. The 'freedom' to produce radical reform stems not just from a WORLDS OF WELFARE high concentration of political authority, but from that factor combined with a number of other features of a particular configuration. In analysing the dynamics of social policy restructuring, one needs to What follows i a preliminary, attempt to outline the distinct politics of attend to both the particular scale and shape of welfare states and par- welfare state reform in the three 'worlds', or regimes, of liberal, social ticular political- contexts. With respect to the latter, the scope of popular democratic, and conservative welfare states." I argue that the basic frame- support for social provision, the connections between social provision and work developed in Section 1 is helpful for making sense of what is happening systems of economic production, and the relationship between the electoral/ in each of these three worlds. Each world, however, is composed not only partisan arena and systems of interest intermediation are especially critical. of particular types of welfare states, but also of distinct political settings. In short, we need-to recognize the existence of distinct worlds of welfare Thus, the agendas for welfare state restructuring and the dominant polit- capitalism. ical coalitions will vary. Furthermore, we can expect additional variation across cases within each world, and one of the major tasks for analysts should be to identify and explain that variation. 12 Again though, Swank's chapter suggests that while fragmented institutions might impede retrenchment efforts, they are also likely to slow welfare state expansion in the first place. This slowdown occurs both because of institutional fragmentation's direct role in blocking " A number of the cases sometimes considered in such comparisons are excluded from reform and because of its indirect negative effects on social solidarity through the promotion this analysis. Greece, Ireland, Portugal, and Spain are late developing welfare states, which of interest heterogeneity. This is in keeping with a general presumption in much institutional were still very much in the process of welfare state construction at the end of the golden research, namely, that the effects of institutions will generally be multiple and cross-cutting age. In my view this context raises quite different issues from those cases where affluence rather than simply direct and unidimensional. A different way to put this is that we need to had been achieved and welfare states were already close to maturity by the mid-1970s. distinguish between the short-term and long-term causal effects of institutional fragmentation. Switzerlancrand Japan represent distinct configurations that do not fit easily into any of the For a discussion of this point, see Shalev 1999. three regimes. 432 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 433 By distinguishing among regimes, and disaggregating different dimensions The political constellations of these cases also share a number of common of restructuring, one can identify patterns that would not be evident in a more features. First, and most crucial is the weakness of encompassing interest unified analysis which tried to explain a single outcome (e.g. 'retrenchment') organizations. By comparative standards these are cases where organized over the whole set of cases. In these respects, I follow Esping-Andersen's regime labour has modest political capacities. Again, there is considerable variation typology (although utilizing different outcome dimensions). On the other 9. mong these countries, ranging from Australia at one end to the United States hand, our accounts of the political dynamics in the three regimes are quite at the other. It is not only that labour is weak in these cases; the capacities different.' 4 The goal is to make the investigation complicated enough to cap- of employers for collective action are also limited. In Soskice's words, ture and account for crucial elements of diversity, but not so complicated `comp,anies have little capacity to coordinate their activities collectively. Their that it becomes impossible to identify general patterns. inability to act collectively means that they cannot combine to negotiate dis- cretionary framework solutions with the state' (1999: 110). In short, with the partial exception of Australia, not only does labour lack the power to The Liberal Regime veto change, but the capacity of these systems to pursue negotiated reform through systems of organized interest intermediation is very low. Unlike the The liberal cases include Australia, Canada, Great Britain, New Zealand, case in other welfare state regimes, policy changes must be executed almost and the United States. 15 The most politically salient features of the welfare exclusively through electoral and partisan politics. state constellations in these countries include the following (data on most Several crucial features of the electoral/partisan environments thus of these features can be found in the Huber and Stephens chapter in this deserve special emphasis. First, until New Zealand's recent reform, none of volume). Taxes, and spending, have remained low by international standards. these cases employed proportional representation. Instead, 'first-past-the-post' Public sector service employment is also low. Many transfer programmes 16 electoral systems have been the norm. Thus, all of these countries have had are income-tested, although the range of coverage varies from very narrow strong tendencies towards two (or two-and-a-half) party systems. With the (the United States) to quite broad (Australia). In part as a consequence of... exception of the United States, where division between Congress and the the failure of the welfare state to meet demands for social provision, private'''. President has become the norm, these systems tended to produce single-party sector activity in pensions and social services such as child care (as well as governments. They varied, however, in the extent to which political institu- health care in the United States and New Zealand) is extensive. In many tions provided checks on these governments. New Zealand (pre-1996) and cases, tax expenditures subsidize private provision for the upper middle class Great Britain conslitute pure 'Westminster' models of 'elected dictatorship'. (e.g. Howard 1997). Finally, these welfare state arrangements operate in the By contrast, the fetleral systems of Australia, Canada, and the United States context of liberal market economies. There is no overlap between the world create additional veto points, the severity and nature of which varies across of libefal welfare states and the world of 'organized market economies'. Thus, countries, issue area, and electoral context. there are numerous linkages, explored below, between liberal welfare state - Furthermore, there is little question that the scope of popular support arrangements- and the liberal or 'disorganized' model of capitalism. for public social provision tends to be more conditional in these cases, although again with considerable variation (Svallfors 1997). One can see here how This is not an issue that Esping-Andersen has pursued in detail. In Three Worlds he multiple features of a particular configuration point in the same direction. identified distinct political cleavages in each regime. In Postindustrial Economies he seems to Because these welfare states are relatively small, the 'core' support group maintain, although without much elaboration, that 'path dependence' and 'median voters' for social provision is also relatively small. Reliance on means-testing may will prevent major policy change. The current analysis points to quite different political cleav- divide those who benefit from many taxpayers. The political clout of labour ages in the three worlds and argues that while path dependence and pivotal voters channel reform, they are unlikely to prevent it. unions, a traditional bastion of support, is also relatively modest. The 15 F. G. Castles and Mitchell (1993) have persuasively argued that the two Antipode coun- institutionalizaticin of (often state-subsidized) market alternatives weakens tries should be seen as a distinct 'wage-earner' model, in which protectionism combined with middle-class attachments to public provision. High levels of inequality are also intensive labour market regulation to produce relatively egalitarian outcomes without extens- associated, in many countries, with large class biases in electoral turnout. ive formal welfare states. However, the wage-earner model, grounded in protectionism, came under acute pressures from a changing international economy. For these countries globaliza- Low turnout among the economically vulnerable further diminishes their tion has clearly mattered enormously. This alternative model began to break down in the already liwited political influence. mid-1970s, forcing a gradual shift towards broadly liberal arrangements. Australia, in par- ticular, remains somewhat distinct from other liberal cases in the continuing role of politically mediated wage bargaining. The differences are less pronounced than they were two decades " Australia employs a 'preferential' voting system. Because voter's second choice matters, ago, however, especially following the recent period of Liberal—National governance. this will generally induce parties to moderate their policy stance. 434 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 435 To be absolutely clear, the claim is not that a majority of voters tend to social assistance have been severely weakened. Provincial and state author- oppose the welfare state in these countries; nowhere is this true. Compared ities have often moved aggressively to push the poor off social assistance to the social democratic and Continental countries, however, pivotal voters rolls and into the workforce. are likely to possess weaker attachments to social provision, and to be more At first glance, this characteristic of liberal regime reform is puzzling. susceptible to alternative political appeals (such as the demand for tax cuts). Why would these systems, already the most `commodified' in the OECD, I Liberal welfare states thus provide the greatest potential for parties to re- rush so much more aggressively in this direction? Part of the answer lies in concile political success and a relatively aggressive, even openly hostile stance the political weakness of those who might resist commodification. Equally vis-a-vis significant components of the welfare state. Under particular con- i mportant, however, is the connection between income support and the ditions, pivotal voters may be within reach, and in some of these countries labour'market in political economies where wage flexibility is treated as labour can be essentially excluded from playing a significant role. Thus, the the principal buffer against high unemployment. The deteriorating market political conflict between advocates of moderate restructuring and radical position of low-skilled workers has confronted policy makers everywhere with retrenchment is more equally matched than it is in the other two regimes. difficifit trade-offs (Iversen and Wren 1998; Scharpf 1997b). Consistent This is reflected in the pattern of outcomes. By comparative standards, with the basic workings of a liberal, 'disorganized' market economy, all of quite radical cutbacks have been achieved in New Zealand, and, to a lesser these liberal countries have implicitly accepted that the new environment extent, in Great Britain (Stephens, Huber, and Ray 1999; Castles and Pierson requires larger wage differentials, and, in particular, deteriorating relative 1996). Canada and Australia, on the other hand, have pursued a distinctive wage conditions among the low-skilled. Yet this deterioration can only be course, also marked by efforts at cost containment and commodification, carried out if exit options (`reservation wages') are not attractive. That is, the but balanced by serious efforts to protect the most vulnerable. In the push for (downward) flexibility among the low-skilled implies a hardening United States, change has been more limited, and contains elements of both of conditions for income support to those out of work. Improving 'work tendencies. incentives' has thus been a common frame of reform, justifying stricter Although the variations across countries both in policy outcomes aqd eligibility, benefit cigs, or even outright abolition of programmes. in inequality trends are quite striking, these outcomes are not sufficientry- Many comparative analysts view the liberal welfare states primarily as stable to allow firm conclusions about national trajectories. Australia's cur- an analytical or normative foil for the 'real' welfare states of Continental rent National–Liberal government is seeking to erode many of the provisions Europe and Scandinavia. For these analysts, the policy changes just described that marked the accords reached between the Australian Labour govern- are taken to definF the essential outcomes for/these cases. From this per- ments and the trade unions between 1983 and 1995. Under the current,British spective, the Unified States is taken to typify the liberal world, and the Labour government, important new policy initiatives emulate' some of the welfare 'reform' which abolished Aid to Families with Dependent Children Canadian and Australian strategies which combine a strengthening of work is taken as the paradigmatic policy change in the USA. Social policy dis- incentives with compensatory policies for those affected (Hills 1998). These mantling and re-commodification are portrayed as the logical political recent developments suggest that partisan control of government may be most destination for liberal welfare states in the new era. important in the liberal regime. This is indeed what we should expect given The actual patterns, however, are both more complex and more inter- the relatively narrow base of welfare state support in these countries, and esting. All the liberal welfare states have shared in the shift towards re- the dominance a the electoral/partisan arena for political action. commodification, albeit at different paces and to differentdegrees. Yet there A defining characteristic of restructuring in all the liberal welfare states has has been considerable variation in the extent to which this transition has been the priority placed on re-commodification. Indeed, both the emphasis been subsidized or buffered. The main political debate in the liberal welfare placed on commodification and the degree of change has clearly been states has not focused on whether or not low-skilled workers should be in the greater than in the other welfare state regimes. In all the liberal welfare states, labour market, but on the terms under which their participation should take programmes providing transfer payments to those of working age but out of place. The key issue is the extent to which commodification should be sub- the labour force—unemployment benefit and social assistance—have faced sidized. Those advocating subsidization have accepted demands for reform major cutbacks. Eligibility rules have been tightened, and benefit levels have in social assistance and unemployment benefit, but have sought to 'make been reduced significantly. Coverage rates (in Canada and the United States) work pay' by supplementing poverty-level wages available in an unregulated and benefit levels (everywhere) for the unemployed have fallen sharply. Most market withi'various forms of targeted social provision. Arguments in favour dramatically, in Canada and the United States, national commitments to of such provisions emphasize both social equity concerns and the need to 436 Paul Pierson Coping with Permanent Austerity 437 foster the development of human capital. Many of these supplements are appears to facilitate a focus on expenditure (and tax) restraint, along with targeted on groups that are considered particularly vulnerable and/or par- deficit reduction, even in the absence of an institutional forcing mechanism ticularly deserving of support, especially households with children. such as EMU." The particular package of supplements varies, but may include some Cost containment efforts, however, have not on the whole generated the or all of the following: improved child allowances and access to affordable kjnd of radical roll-backs popularly associated with neoliberalism. Indeed, child care, reductions in social insurance contributions for the low-paid, an it is hard to discern a distinct liberal response in the big spending areas of increased minimum wage," expanded access to public health insurance (in health and pensions. Unlike the case of income maintenance for the able- Ithe United States), and the expansion or introduction of tax-based wage sup- bodied, there is no clear policy imperative. In both health care and pensions, plements. The last provision has been particularly important. All the liberal outcomes appear to be heavily constrained by the particular policy arrange- countries have introduced significant wage subsidies, operated through sys- ments established before cost-containment demands became paramount. tems of taxation, for at least some of the working poor—usually families Where there were well-established, deeply embedded policy frameworks in with children. Most dramatic has been the major expansion of the Earned these areas, continuity has been more evident than change. Thus, in health Income Tax Credit in the United States and of the Working Families Tax care, Australia, Britain, and Canada have all made modifications of their Credit (formerly Family Credit), in Great Britain. In Australia, the univer- pre-existing systems in an attempt to cut costs, but without challenging sal child benefit was means-tested (although 60 per cent of the population basic rights to quality care and in contexts where overall expenditures remain eligible), but an expanded Additional Family Payment provided were increasing. In the United States, the major policy initiative was a failed significant additional cash on a per child basis to working families. attempt to dramatically expand health care coverage, albeit as part of a cost- Some of these subsidization initiatives could be dismissed as cosmetic containment strategy. New Zealand again stands out as a divergent case. embellishments to harsh exercises in retrenchment. Yet the overall scale Only there was a major effoirt undertaken to roll back the contours of state of these mediating efforts is difficult to ignore. In the United States, for provision for health care. I instance, while there were considerable cutbacks in AFDC and Unemplo)k As Giaimo's chapter demonstrates, there is no logic of liberal market ment Insurance even before the 1996 welfare reform, overall federal spending economies that generates a strong push for market expansion and state con- on low-income groups rose significantly in the late 1980s and the first half traction in the area of health care. On the contrary, a good case can be made of the 1990s (Weaver 1998). By the time AFDC was transformed and largely for the opposite proposition: a strong state-role in health care will gener- handed over to the states, the federal government was spending twice as much ally serve the interests of most employers. The Clinton administration's reform

Use Quizgecko on...
Browser
Browser