Consumer Choice Theory PDF
Document Details
Uploaded by WellRoundedPointOfView
Institute of Business Administration (IBA)
Tags
Summary
This document explores the theory of consumer choice in economics. It examines how consumers make decisions based on their budget constraints and preferences, using pizza and Pepsi as examples. The text discusses indifference curves, marginal rate of substitution, and various optimization methods. It also touches upon topics such as utility and how changes in income and prices affect consumer choices.
Full Transcript
## The Theory of Consumer Choice ### Introduction - Consumers face Trade offs - Theory of consumer choice examines trade-offs consumers face - Ex: Buy more of one good = buy less of others, Spend more time on leisure = less income = less consumption - Analyzes how consumers make decisions and r...
## The Theory of Consumer Choice ### Introduction - Consumers face Trade offs - Theory of consumer choice examines trade-offs consumers face - Ex: Buy more of one good = buy less of others, Spend more time on leisure = less income = less consumption - Analyzes how consumers make decisions and respond to changes in their environment. - Applies theory to three key household decisions: - Do all demand curves slope downward? - How do wages affect labor supply? - How interest rates affect household saving? - These questions seemingly unrelated - Theory of consumer choice can be used to address all of them ### 21-1 The Budget Constraint: What the Consumer Can Afford - **Budget constraint** is the limit on consumption bundles a consumer can afford. - Consumers often desire more goods, but income limits how much they can buy. - Simple model: Consumer buys only Pizza and Pepsi (represents all goods and services) - Income = $1,000, Pizza Price = $10, Pepsi Price = $2 - Table and graph show possible combinations of Pizza and Pepsi **Figure 1: The Consumer's Budget Constraint** | Number of Pizzas | Liters of Pepsi | Spending on Pizza | Spending on Pepsi | Total Spending | |---|---|---|---|---| | 100 | 0 | $1,000 | $0 | $1,000 | | 90 | 50 | $900 | $100 | $1,000 | | 80 | 100 | $800 | $200 | $1,000 | | 70 | 150 | $700 | $300 | $1,000 | | 60 | 200 | $600 | $400 | $1,000 | | 50 | 250 | $500 | $500 | $1,000 | | 40 | 300 | $400 | $600 | $1,000 | | 30 | 350 | $300 | $700 | $1,000 | | 20 | 400 | $200 | $800 | $1,000 | | 10 | 450 | $100 | $900 | $1,000 | | 0 | 500 | $0 | $1,000 | $1,000 | - **Budget Constraint** is a line that shows all possible consumption bundles a consumer can afford. - **Slope** of the Budget Constraint reflects the relative price of the goods. - Pizza costs 5 times as much as Pepsi, so one pizza can be traded for 5 liters of Pepsi. - **Slope** of the Budget Constraint is 5 liters per pizza. ### 21-2 Preferences: What the Consumer Wants - Budget Constraint shows what the consumer can afford. - Preferences show the consumer's desires. - **Indifference Curves** show combinations of goods that give the consumer the same level of satisfaction. - The consumer is equally happy with any point on the same Indifference Curve. **Figure 2: The Consumer's Preferences** - Higher Indifference Curves are preferred to lower ones. - **Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)** shows the rate at which the consumer is willing to trade one good for another. - Ex: How much Pepsi is the consumer willing to give up to get one extra pizza. - The MRS depends on how much of each good the consumer is already consuming. #### 21-2a Representing Preferences with Indifference Curves - **Properties of Indifference Curves** - Higher indifference curves are preferred: Consumers prefer more goods to less. - They are downward sloping: If the quantity of one good decreases, the quantity of the other must increase to maintain the same level of satisfaction. - They do not cross: Crossing would mean that the consumer is equally happy with two bundles, even though one bundle has more of both goods, contradicting the preference for more. - They are bowed inwards: Reflects the diminishing MRS, meaning the consumer is willing to trade a smaller quantity of the good they have more of to get one more of the good they have less of (ex: willing to give up larger amounts of Pepsi for the first few pizzas than for later pizzas). #### 21-2b Four Properties of Indifference Curves - **Perfect substitutes:** Goods that are easily interchangeable (Ex: Nickels & Dimes). Indifference curves are straight lines, showing a constant MRS. - **Perfect complements:** Goods that must be consumed in a fixed ratio (Ex: Left & Right Shoes). Indifference curves are right angles, showing that additional units of one good have no value without the other. #### 21-2c Two Extreme Examples of Indifference Curves - Most goods are neither perfect substitutes or complements, but have indifference curves that are bowed inward. ### 21-3 Optimization: What the Consumer Chooses - Goal: Find the best combination of goods within the consumer's budget. - Highest Indifference Curve the consumer can reach is tangent (touching) to the Budget Constraint at the **optimum**. **Figure 6: The Consumer's Optimum** - The point where the indifference curve and the budget constraint touch is the optimum. - The slope of the Indifference Curve (MRS) equals the slope of the Budget Constraint (Relative Price). - The consumer values the goods at the same rate as the market. #### 21-3a The Consumer's Optimal Choices - **Utility** is an alternate way to represent preferences. - Utility is the satisfaction a consumer gets from a bundle of goods. - Higher Indifference Curves = Higher Utility - **Marginal Utility:** The extra satisfaction a consumer gets from consuming one more unit of the good. - The MRS equals the ratio of marginal utilities of the two goods. - At the optimum, the marginal utility per dollar is the same for all goods. #### 21-3b How Changes in Income Affect the Consumer's Choices - **Normal good:** A good for which the quantity demanded increases as income increases. - **Inferior good:** A good for which the quantity demanded decreases as income increases. **Figure 7: An Increase in Income** - Increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward, allowing the consumer to buy more of both goods (assuming both goods are normal). - The new optimum is on a higher indifference curve, showing increased satisfaction. **Figure 8: An Inferior Good** - Increase in income shifts the budget constraint outward, leading the consumer to consume more of a normal good (pizza) but less of an inferior good (Pepsi). #### 21-3c How Changes in Price Affect the Consumer's Choices - **Price change** shifts the budget constraint outward and changes its slope. **Figure 9: A Change in Price** - Lower price of Pepsi shifts the budget constraint outward and becomes steeper, meaning the consumer can trade a pizza for a higher quantity of Pepsi. - The new optimum is on a higher indifference curve showing increased satisfaction. #### 21-3d Income and Substitution Effects - **Income Effect:** Change in consumption due to a price change moving the consumer to a higher or lower indifference curve. - **Substitution Effect:** Change in consumption due to a price change, moving the consumer along the same indifference curve to a point with a new MRS. **Table 1: Income and Substitution Effects When the Price of Pepsi Falls** | Good | Income Effect | Substitution Effect | Total Effect | |---|---|---|---| | Pepsi | Consumer is richer, so she buys more Pepsi | Pepsi is relatively cheaper, so consumer buys more Pepsi | Income and substitution effects act in the same direction, so consumer buys more Pepsi. | | Pizza | Consumer is richer, so she buys more pizza | Pizza is relatively more expensive, so consumer buys less pizza. | Income and substitution effects act in opposite directions, so the total effect on pizza consumption is ambiguous. | **Figure 10: Income and Substitution Effects** - When the price of Pepsi falls, the consumer moves from the initial optimum to the new optimum. This change can be broken down into two steps: 1. **Substitution Effect:** The consumer moves along the initial indifference curve to a point with the new MRS, where the indifference curve's slope matches the new relative price. 2. **Income Effect:** Consumer shifts to a higher indifference curve, reflecting the increase in purchasing power due to the price change. - Shows that the consumer will always buy more of the good whose price has fallen, but the impact on the demand for the other good is uncertain. #### 21-3e Deriving the Demand Curve - **Demand Curve:** Shows quantity demanded of a good at different prices. - Arises from the consumer's optimization of their preferences within their budget constraint. **Figure 11: Deriving the Demand Curve** - Panel (a) shows a fall in the price of Pepsi moving the consumer to a new optimum with a higher quantity demanded. - Panel (b) shows the corresponding demand curve reflecting the relationship between price and quantity demanded. ### 21-4 Three Applications The theory of consumer choice can be used to explain: - **Downward sloping demand curves:** When the price of a good decreases, the consumer substitutes the now relatively cheaper good for more expensive goods. - **Labor supply decisions:** Higher wages can lead to both a substitution effect (more earnings = more leisure) and an income effect (more earnings = less need for work). - **Saving and borrowing decisions:** Higher interest rates can lead to a substitution effect (more rewards for saving) and an income effect (more rewards for saving = less need to save). ### Conclusion The Theory of Consumer Choice is a valuable tool for understanding how individuals make decisions given their limited resources, preferences, and changes in prices and income. It provides a framework for analyzing various economic questions and demonstrates the importance of optimizing choices to maximize consumer satisfaction and welfare.