Saez et al (2012) The Elasticity of Taxable Income PDF
Document Details
Uploaded by AppreciatedUranium
University of Bern
2012
Emmanuel Saez, Joel Slemrod, and Seth H. Giertz
Tags
Summary
This is a review of the literature on the elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates using tax return data. The paper outlines a theoretical framework and discusses key empirical analyses. The authors also propose avenues for future research.
Full Transcript
Journal of Economic Literature 2012, 50:1, 3–50 http://dx/doi=10.1257/jel.50.1.3 The Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates: A Critical Review Emmanuel Saez, J...
Journal of Economic Literature 2012, 50:1, 3–50 http://dx/doi=10.1257/jel.50.1.3 The Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates: A Critical Review Emmanuel Saez, Joel Slemrod, and Seth H. Giertz* This paper critically surveys the large and growing literature estimating the elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates using tax return data. First, we provide a theoretical framework showing under what assumptions this elasticity can be used as a sufficient statistic for efficiency and optimal tax analysis. We discuss what other parameters should be estimated when the elasticity is not a sufficient statistic. Second, we discuss conceptually the key issues that arise in the empirical estimation of the elasticity of taxable income using the example of the 1993 top individual income tax rate increase in the United States to illustrate those issues. Third, we provide a critical discussion of selected empirical analyses of the elasticity of taxable income in light of the theoretical and empirical framework we laid out. Finally, we discuss avenues for future research. ( JEL H24, H31, J22) 1. Introduction respect to the marginal tax rate. Indeed, until recently, the labor supply elasticity was the T he notion of a behavioral elasticity occu- pies a critical place in the economic anal- ysis of taxation. Graduate textbooks teach closest thing that public finance economics had to a central parameter. In a static model where people value only two commodities— that the two central aspects of the public leisure and a composite consumption good— sector, optimal progressivity of the tax-and- the real wage in terms of the consumption transfer system, as well as the optimal size of good is the only relative price at issue. This the public sector, depend (inversely) on the real wage is equal to the amount of goods compensated elasticity of labor supply with that can be consumed per hour of leisure foregone (or, equivalently, per hour of labor * Saez: University of California, Berkeley, and NBER. supplied). At the margin, substitution possi- Slemrod: University of Michigan and NBER. Giertz: bilities, and therefore the excess burden of University of Nebraska. We thank Sören Blomquist, Raj Chetty, Henrik Kleven, Wojciech Kopczuk, Håkan Selin, taxation, can be captured by a compensated Jonathan Shaw, Caroline Weber, David Weiner, Roger Gor- labor supply elasticity. don, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments With some notable exceptions, the profes- and discussions, and Jonathan Adams and Caroline Weber for invaluable research assistance. Financial support from sion has settled on a value for this elasticity NSF Grant SES-0134946 is gratefully acknowledged. close to zero for prime-age males, although 3 01_Saez.indd 3 2/27/12 3:49 PM 4 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) for married women the responsiveness of accurately summarizing the marginal effi- labor force participation appears to be sig- ciency cost of taxation than a narrower mea- nificant. Overall, though, the compensated sure of taxpayer response such as the labor elasticity of labor appears to be fairly small. supply elasticity, and therefore is a worthy In models with only a labor–leisure choice, topic of investigation. this implies that the efficiency cost per dollar Although the literature reviewed in this raised of taxing labor income—to redistrib- article addresses the behavioral response ute revenue to others or to provide public to individual income taxation, many of the goods—is bound to be low, as well. issues apply to any tax base. Certainly the idea Although evidence of a substantial com- that, under some assumptions, all responses pensated labor supply elasticity has been are symptoms of inefficiency applies gener- hard to find, evidence that taxpayers respond ally. For example, consider a state imposing to tax system changes more generally has a cigarette excise tax. Under some assump- decidedly not been hard to find. For exam- tions, the central empirical parameter is the ple, the timing of capital gains realizations elasticity of the cigarette tax base, which appears to react strongly to changes in capi- includes not only the response of smoking to tal gains tax rates, as evidenced by the surge tax rate changes but also the impact on the in capital gains realizations in 1986, after the tax base of smuggling and tax-free Internet United States announced increased tax rates purchases. on realizations beginning in 1987 (Auerbach The new focus (on the ETI) raises the 1988). Dropping the top individual tax rate possibility that the efficiency cost of taxa- to below the corporate tax rate in the same tion is significantly higher than is implied if act led to a significant shift in business activ- labor supply is the sole, or principal, mar- ity toward pass-through entities, which are gin of behavioral response. Indeed, some not subject to the corporate tax (Auerbach of the first empirical estimates of the elas- and Slemrod 1997). ticity of taxable income implied very sizable Addressing these other margins of behav- responses and therefore a very high marginal ioral response is crucial because, under some efficiency cost of funds. However, the subse- assumptions, all responses to taxation are quent literature found substantially smaller symptomatic of deadweight loss. Taxes trig- elasticities, and raised questions about both ger a host of behavioral responses intended our ability to identify this key parameter and to minimize the burden on the individual. In about the claim that it alone is a sufficient the absence of externalities or other market statistic for welfare analysis of the tax sys- failure, and putting aside income effects, all tem. Whether the taxable income elasticity such responses are sources of inefficiency, is an accurate indicator of the revenue leak- whether they take the form of reduced labor age due to behavioral response, the ultimate supply, increased charitable contributions indicator of efficiency cost, depends on the or mortgage interest payments, increased situation. First, if revenue leakage in cur- expenditures for tax professionals, or a dif- rent year tax revenue is substantially offset ferent form of business organization, and by revenue gain in other years or in other tax thus they add to the burden of taxes from bases, it is misleading. Second, if some of the society’s perspective. Because in principle response involves changes in activities with the elasticity of taxable income (which we externalities, such as charitable giving behav- abbreviate from now on using the stan- ior, then the elasticity is not a sufficient sta- dard acronym ETI) can capture all of these tistic for welfare analysis. Third, the elasticity responses, it holds the promise of more depends on the tax system. A tax system with 01_Saez.indd 4 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 5 a narrow base and many deductions and other margins such as intensity of work, avoidance opportunities is likely to generate career choices, form and timing of com- high elasticities and hence large efficiency pensation, tax avoidance, or tax evasion. As costs. In that context, broadening the tax a result, an individual’s wage rate w might base and eliminating avoidance opportuni- depend on effort and respond to tax rates, ties such as to reduce the elasticity is likely and reported taxable income might differ to be more efficient and more equitable than from w · l as individuals split their gross altering tax rates within the old system. earnings between taxable cash compensation The remainder of the paper is organized and nontaxable compensation such as fringe as follows. Section 2 presents the theoretical benefits, or even fail to report their full tax- framework underlying the taxable income able income because of tax evasion. elasticity concept. Section 3 presents the key As shown by Feldstein (1999), a simple identification issues that arise in the empiri- way to model all those behavioral responses cal estimation of the taxable income elastic- is to posit that utility depends positively ity, using as an illustration the taxable income on disposable income (equal to consump- response to the 1993 top tax rate increase tion) c and negatively on reported income z in the United States. Section 4 reviews the (because activities that generate income are results of some selected empirical studies in costly, for example because they may require light of our discussion of the conceptual and foregoing leisure). Hence, individuals choose empirical issues. Section 5 concludes and (c, z) to maximize a utility function u(c, z) discusses the most promising avenues for subject to a budget constraint of the form future research. Appendices present a sum- c = (1 − τ) · z + E. Such maximization mary of the key U.S. legislated tax changes generates an individual “reported income” that have been studied in the U.S. literature supply function z(1 − τ, E) where z depends and a brief description of existing U.S. tax on the net-of-marginal-tax rate 1 − τ and return data. virtual income E generated by the tax/trans- fer system.1 Each individual has a particular reported income supply function reflecting 2. Conceptual Framework his/her skills, taste for labor, opportunities for avoidance, and so on.2 2.1 Basic Model In most of what follows, we assume away In the standard labor supply model, indi- income effects so that the income func- viduals maximize a utility function u(c, l) tion z does not depend on E and depends where c is disposable income, equal to con- sumption in a one-period model, and l is labor supply measured by hours of work. 1 This reported income supply function remains valid in Earnings are given by w · l, where w is the the case of nonlinear tax schedules as c = (1 − τ)z + E is exogenous wage rate. The (linearized) bud- the linearized budget constraint at the utility-maximizing get constraint is c = w · l · (1 − τ) + E, point, just as in the basic labor supply model. 2 We could have posited a more general model in where τ is the marginal tax rate and E is vir- which c = y − τ z + E, where y is real income and z is tual income. reported income that may differ from real income because of, for example, tax evasion and avoidance. Utility would The taxable income elasticity literature be u(c, y, y − z) which is increasing in c, decreasing in y generalizes this model by noting that hours (earnings effort), and decreasing in y − z (costs of avoid- of work are only one component of the ing or evading taxes). Such a utility function would still generate a reported income supply function of the form behavioral response to income taxation. z(1 − τ, E) and our analysis would go through. We come Individuals can respond to taxation through back to such a more general model in section 2.4. 01_Saez.indd 5 2/27/12 3:49 PM 6 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) only on the net-of-tax rate.3 In the absence (1999), this elasticity captures not only the of compelling evidence about significant hours of work response, but also all other income effects in the case of overall reported behavioral responses to marginal tax rates. income, it seems reasonable to consider the Furthermore, it depends on features of the case with no income effects, which simpli- tax system, such as the availability of deduc- fies considerably the presentation of effi- tions, and other avoidance opportunities—a ciency effects. It might seem unintuitive to very important point for the interpretation assume away the effect of changes in exog- of empirical results, as we discuss below. enous income on (reported taxable) income. Therefore, the elasticity is not a structural However, in the reported income context, E parameter depending solely on individual is defined exclusively as virtual income cre- preferences. ated by the tax/transfer budget constraint As we discuss later, a number of empiri- and hence is not part of taxable income z. cal studies have found that the behavioral Another difference is that the labor compo- response to changes in marginal tax rates nent of z is labor income (w · l) rather than is concentrated in the top of the income labor hours (l); this difference requires us distribution, with less evidence of any to address the incidence of tax rate changes response for the middle and upper-middle (i.e., their effect on w), which we do briefly income class (see sections 3 and 4 below).4 in section 2.2.5. Moreover, in the United States, because of The ETI literature has attempted to esti- graduated rates as well as exemptions and mate the elasticity of reported incomes with low-income tax credits, individual income tax respect to the net-of-tax rate, defined as liabilities are very skewed: the top quintile (top percentile) tax filers remitted 86.3 per- (1) 1 − e = _ τ · _ ∂ z , cent (39.1 percent) of all individual income z ∂ (1 − τ) taxes in 2006 (Congressional Budget Office 2009). Therefore, it is useful to focus on the the percent change in reported income analysis of the effects of changing the mar- when the net-of-tax rate increases by 1 per- ginal tax rate on the upper end of the income cent. With no income effects, this elasticity is distribution. Let us therefore assume that equal to both the compensated and uncom- incomes in the top bracket, above a given _ pensated elasticity. Importantly, and as rec- reported income threshold z , face a constant ognized in the labor supply literature, the marginal tax rate τ. 5 elasticity for a given individual may not be As in the conceptual framework just constant and depends on the tax system. As a described, we assume that individual incomes result, an elasticity estimated around the cur- reported in the top bracket depend on the rent tax system may not apply to a hypotheti- net-of-tax rate 1 − τ. Let us assume that there _ cal large tax change. As shown in Feldstein are N individuals in the top bracket (above z ) 4 The behavioral response at the low end of the income 3There is no consensus in the labor supply literature distribution is for the most part out of the scope of the pres- about the size of income effects, with many studies obtain- ent paper. The large literature on responses to welfare and ing small income effects, but with several important studies income transfer programs targeted toward low incomes finding large income effects (see Blundell and MaCurdy has, however, displayed evidence of significant labor supply 1999 for a survey). There is much less empirical evidence responses (see, e.g., Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001). on the magnitude of income effects in the reported income 5 For example, in the case of tax year 2008 federal literature. Gruber and Saez (2002) estimate both income income _ tax law in the United States, taxable incomes above and substitution effects in the case of reported incomes, z = $357,700 are taxed at the top marginal tax rate of and find small and insignificant income effects. τ = 0.35. 01_Saez.indd 6 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 7 when the top bracket rate is τ. We denote revenue due to the behavioral response is by zm(1 − τ) the average income reported by equal to those N top taxpayers, as a function of the net-of-tax rate. The aggregate elasticity of tax- (3) dB ≡ −N · e · zm · _τ . d τ < 0. 1−τ able income in the top bracket with respect to the net-of-tax rate is therefore defined Summing the mechanical and the behavioral as e = [(1 − τ)/zm] · [∂ zm /∂ (1 − τ)]. This effect, we obtain the total change in tax rev- aggregate elasticity is equal to the average of enue due to the tax change: the individual elasticities weighted by indi- vidual income, so that individuals contribute (4) dR = dM + dB to the aggregate elasticity in proportion to _ their incomes.6 − z) = N · (zm [ ] Suppose that the government increases the top tax rate τ by a small amount d τ · 1 − e · _ zm τ · d τ. _ · _ (with no change in the tax schedule for z − z 1 − τ m _ incomes below z ). This small tax reform has _ two effects on tax revenue. First, there is a Let us denote by a the ratio z m/(zm − z). “mechanical” increase in tax revenue due to Note that in general a ≥ 1, and that a = 1 the fact that taxpayers face a higher tax rate when a single flat tax rate applies to all _ on their incomes above z . The total mechani- incomes, as in this case the top bracket starts _ cal effect is at zero (z = 0). If the top tail of the distribu- tion is Pareto distributed,8 then the parame- _ _ (2) − z) · d τ > 0. dM ≡ N · (zm ter a does not vary with z and is exactly equal to the Pareto parameter. As the tails of actual This mechanical effect is the projected income distributions are very well approxi- increase in tax revenue, absent any behav- mated by Pareto distributions, within a given ioral response. year, the coefficient a is extremely stable in _ Second, the increase in the tax rate triggers the United States for z above $300,000 and a behavioral response that reduces the aver- equals approximately 1.5 in recent years.9 age reported income of top N taxpayers by The parameter a measures the thinness of d zm = −e · zm · dτ/(1 − τ).7 A change in the top tail of the income distribution: the reported income of dzm changes tax revenue by τ d zm. Hence, the aggregate change in tax 8 A Pareto distribution has a density function of the form f (z) = C/z1+α, where C and α are constant parameters. The parameter α is called the Pareto parameter. _ In that m 6 Formally, z = [z1 +.. + zN]/N and hence case, zm = ∫ z · f_(z)· dz/∫_z ∞ _z∞ f (z) · dz = z · α/(α − 1) /(z − z) = α. m e = [(1 − τ)/z ] · [∂ z /∂ (1 − τ)] m m and hence z m 9 Saez (2001) provides such an empirical analysis for = (1 − τ) · [∂ z1 /∂ (1 − τ) +.. + ∂ zN/∂ (1 − τ)]/[N · zm ] = [e1· z1+.. + eN · zN ]/[z1+.. + zN ], 1992 and 1993 reported wage incomes using U.S. tax return data. Piketty _ and Saez (2003) provide estimates where eiis the elasticity of individual i. of thresholds z and average incomes z m corresponding to 7 The change d τ could induce a small fraction d N of the various fractiles within the top decile of the U.S. income N taxpayers to leave (or join if d τ < 0) the top bracket. distribution from 1913 to 2008, allowing a straightforward As long as behavioral responses take place only along the estimation of the parameter a for any year and income intensive margin, each individual response is proportional threshold. As U.S. income concentration has increased in to d τ so that the total revenue effect of such responses is recent decades, the Pareto parameter a has correspond- second order (d N · d τ) and hence can be ignored in our ingly fallen from about 2 in the 1970s to about 1.5 in most derivation. recent years. 01_Saez.indd 7 2/27/12 3:49 PM 8 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) thicker the tail of the distribution, the larger cost equal to −dB/dR > 0 on taxpayers. _ is zm relative to z , and hence the smaller is a. We can also define the “marginal efficiency Using the definition of a, we can rewrite cost of funds’’ (MECF) as 1 − dB/dR the effect of the small reform on tax revenue = (1 − τ)/(1 − τ − e · a ·τ). These formu- dR simply as: las are valid for any tax rate τ and income distribution as long as income effects are (5) dR = dM · 1 − _ [ τ · e · a. 1−τ ] assumed away, even if individuals have het- erogeneous utility functions and behavioral elasticities.11 The parameters τ and a are Formula (5) shows that the fraction of tax relatively straightforward to measure, so revenue lost through behavioral responses— that the elasticity parameter e is the central the second term in the square bracket parameter necessary to calculate formulas expression—is a simple function increas- (5) and (6). Marginal deadweight burden ing in the tax rate τ, the elasticity e, and the or marginal efficiency cost of funds mea- Pareto parameter a. This expression is of pri- sure solely efficiency costs and abstract from mary importance to the welfare analysis of distributional considerations. The optimal taxation because τ · e · a/(1 − τ) is exactly income tax progressivity literature precisely equal to the marginal deadweight burden brings together the efficiency formulas created by the increase in the tax rate, under derived here with welfare weights captur- the assumptions we have made and that we ing distributional concerns. Therefore, the discuss below. This can be seen as follows: behavioral response elasticity is also a key Because of the envelope theorem, the behav- parameter for characterizing optimal pro- ioral response to a small tax change dτ cre- gressivity (Saez 2001). ates no additional welfare loss and thus the To illustrate these formulas, consider the utility loss (measured in dollar terms) cre- following example using U.S. data. In recent ated by the tax increase is exactly equal to the years, for the top 1 percent income cut-off mechanical effect dM.10 However, tax reve- (corresponding approximately to the top 35 nue collected is only dR = dM + dB < dM percent federal income tax bracket in that because dB < 0. Thus −dB represents the year), Piketty and Saez (2003) estimate that extra amount lost in utility over and above a = 1.5. When combining the maximum the tax revenue collected dR. From (5) and federal and average state income, Medicare, because dR = dM + dB, the marginal excess and typical sales tax rates in the United burden per dollar of extra taxes collected is States, the top marginal tax rate for ordinary defined as income is 42.5 percent as of 2009.12 For an (6) − dB/dR = __ e·a·τ . 11 In contrast, the Harberger triangle (Harberger 1−τ−e·a·τ 1964) approximations are valid only for small tax rates. This expression also abstracts from any marginal compli- ance costs caused by raising rates, and from any marginal In other words, for each extra dollar of taxes administrative costs unless dR is interpreted as revenue net raised, the government imposes an extra of administrative costs. See Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2002). 12 A top federal tax rate of 35 percent, combined with an average top state income tax rate of 5.9 percent, the Medicare 2.9 percent payroll tax, and an average sales tax 10 Formally, V(1 − τ, E) = max u(z(1 − τ) + E, z) so rate of 2.3 percent generate a total top marginal tax rate of z _ that d V = uc · (−zdτ + dE) = −uc · (z − z ) d τ. There- 42.5 percent, when considering that state income taxes are fore, the (money-metric) marginal utility cost of the reform deductible when calculating federal income taxes and the is indeed equal to the mechanical tax increase, individual employer’s share of the Medicare tax is deductible for both by individual. state and federal income tax calculations. 01_Saez.indd 8 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 9 elasticity estimate of e = 0.25 (correspond- becomes infinite as raising more tax rev- ing, as we discuss later, to the mid-range of enue becomes impossible. Using our pre- the estimates from the literature), the frac- vious example with e = 0.25 and a = 1.5, tion of tax revenue lost through behavioral the revenue-maximizing tax rate τ* would responses (−dB/dM), should the top tax rate be 72.7 percent, much higher than the cur- be slightly increased, would be 27.7 percent, rent U.S. top tax rate of 42.5 percent when slightly above a quarter of the mechanical combining all taxes. Keeping state income (i.e., ignoring behavioral responses) pro- and sales taxes, and Medicare taxes con- jected increase in tax revenue. In terms of stant, this would correspond to a top federal marginal excess burden, increasing tax rev- individual income tax rate of 68.4 percent, enue by dR = $1 causes a utility loss (equal very substantially higher than the current to the MECF) of 1/(1 − 0.277) = $1.38 for 35 percent but lower than the top federal taxpayers, and hence a marginal excess bur- income tax rate prior to 1982. den of −dB/dR = $0.38, or 38 percent of Note that when the tax system has a single _ the extra $1 tax collected. tax rate (i.e., when z = 0), the tax-revenue- Following the supply-side debates of maximizing rate becomes the well-known the early 1980s, much attention has been expression τ* = 1/(1 + e). As a ≥ 1, the focused on the revenue-maximizing tax rate. revenue-maximizing flat rate is always larger The revenue-maximizing tax rate τ* is such than the revenue-maximizing rate applied to that the bracketed expression in equation (5) high incomes only. This is because increasing is exactly zero when τ = τ*. Rearranging this just the top tax rate collects extra taxes only equation, we obtain the following simple for- on the portion of incomes above the bracket _ mula for the revenue-maximizing tax rate τ* threshold z , but produces a behavioral for the top bracket: response for high-income taxpayers as large as an identical across-the-board increase in τ* = _ 1 marginal tax rates. (7) . 1 + a·e Giertz (2009) applies the formulas pre- sented in this section to tax return data A top tax rate above τ* is inefficient because from published Statistics of Income tables decreasing the tax rate would both increase produced by the Internal Revenue Service the utility of the affected taxpayers with (IRS) to analyze the impact of the potential _ income above z and increase government expiration of the Bush administration tax revenue, which could in principle be used cuts in 2011. Giertz shows that exactly where to benefit other taxpayers.13 The optimal the ETI falls within the range found in the income taxation literature following Mirrlees empirical literature has significant effects (1971) shows that formula (7) is the opti- on the efficiency and revenue implications mal top tax rate if the social marginal util- for tax policy. For example, Giertz reports ity of consumption decreases to zero when that for ETIs of 0.2, 0.5, and 1.0, behav- income is large (see Saez 2001). At the ioral responses would respectively erase 12, tax rate τ*, the marginal excess b urden 31, and 62 percent of the mechanical rev- enue gain. When offsets to payroll and state income taxes are taken into account, these 13 Formally, this a second-best Pareto-inefficient out- numbers increase by 28 percent. Likewise, come as there is a feasible government policy that can pro- estimates for the marginal cost of public duce a Pareto improvement, ignoring the possibility that the utility of some individuals enters negatively in the util- funds and the revenue-maximizing rates are ity functions of others. quite sensitive to this range of ETIs. 01_Saez.indd 9 2/27/12 3:49 PM 10 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) In the basic model we have considered, the change in the initial base z. The alternative ETI e is a sufficient statistic to estimate the tax base z′ can be a different tax base in the efficiency costs of taxation as it is not neces- same time period or the same tax base in a sary to estimate the structural parameters of different time period. The notion of fiscal the underlying individual preferences. Such externality is therefore dependent on the sufficient statistics for welfare and normative scope of the analysis both along the base analysis have been used in various contexts dimension and the time dimension. In the in the field of public economics in recent limit, where the analysis encompasses all years (see Chetty 2009c for a recent survey). tax bases and all time periods (and hence However, it is important to understand the focuses on the total present discounted value limitations of this approach and the strong of total tax revenue), there can by definition assumptions required to apply it, as we show be no fiscal externalities. in the next subsections. To see the implication of income shifting, assume that a fraction s < 1 of the income 2.2 Fiscal Externalities and Income Shifting that disappears from the individual income The analysis has assumed so far that the tax base following the tax rate increase dτ is reduction in reported incomes due to a tax shifted to other bases and is taxed on average rate increase has no other effect on tax rev- at rate t. For example, if half of the reduc- enue. This is a reasonable assumption if tion in individual reported incomes is due to the reduction in incomes is due to reduced increased (untaxed) leisure and half is due labor supply (and hence an increase in to a shift toward the corporate sector, then untaxed leisure time), or due to a shift from s = 1/2 and t would be equal to the effective taxable cash compensation toward untaxed tax rate on corporate income.14 In the general fringe benefits or perquisites (more gener- case, a behavioral response dz now generates ous health insurance, better offices, com- a tax revenue change equal to (τ − s · t) · dz. pany cars, etc.) or tax evasion. However, in As a result, the change in tax revenue due to many instances the reduction in reported the behavioral response becomes: incomes is due in part to a shift away from taxable individual income toward other (8) dB = −N · e · zm · _ τ · dτ 1−τ forms of taxable income such as corporate income, or deferred compensation that will s · t · dτ. + N · e · zm · _ 1−τ be taxable to the individual at a later date (see Slemrod 1998). For example, Slemrod Therefore, formula (5) for the effect of a (1996) and Gordon and Slemrod (2000) small reform on total tax revenue becomes: argue that part of the surge in top individual incomes after the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (9) dR = dM + dB [ ] in the United States, which reduced indi- vidual income tax rates relative to corporate τ − s · t · e · a. = dM · 1 − _ 1−τ tax rates (see appendix A), was due to a shift of taxable income from the corporate sector toward the individual sector. For a tax change in a given base z, we define a fiscal externality as a change in the 14 It is possible to have t > τ, for example if there present value of tax revenue that occurs in are (nontax) advantages to the corporate form. If all the response is shifting (s = 1), dτ > 0 would actually then any tax base z′ other than z due to the behav- lead to behavioral responses increasing total tax revenue ioral response of private agents to the tax and hence reducing deadweight burden. 01_Saez.indd 10 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 11 The same envelope theorem logic applies for burden: (1) the extent to which individual welfare analysis: the income that is shifted income changes in the first tax base z shift to another tax base at the margin does to another form of income that is taxable, not generate any direct change in welfare characterized by parameter s, and (2) the tax because the taxpayer is indifferent between rate t at which the income shifted is taxed. reporting marginal income in the individual In practice, there are many possibilities for income tax base versus the alternative tax such shifting and measuring empirically all base. Therefore, as above, −dB represents the shifting effects is challenging, especially the marginal deadweight burden of the indi- in the case of shifting across time. The recent vidual income tax, and the marginal excess literature has addressed several channels for burden expressed in terms of extra taxes col- such fiscal externalities. Alternatively, one lected can be written as could identify shifting by looking directly at the overall revenue from all sources. dB = __ e · a · (τ − s · t) (10) − _ . 2.2.1 Individual versus Corporate Income dR 1 − τ − e · a · (τ − s · t) Tax Base The revenue-maximizing tax rate (7) Most countries tax corporate profits becomes: with a separate corpor ate income tax.16 Unincorporated business profits (such as 1 + s·t·a·e τ *s = __ (11) > τ*. sole proprietorships or partnerships) are in 1+ a·e general taxed directly at the individual level. If we assume again that a = 1.5, e = 0.25, In the United States, closely held corpora- τ = 0.425, but that half (s = 0.5) of marginal tions with few shareholders (less than 100 income disappearing from the individual base currently) can elect to become Subchapter S is taxed on average at t = 0.3,15 the fraction corporations and be taxed solely at the indi- of revenue lost due to behavioral responses vidual level. Such businesses are also called drops from 27.7 percent to 17.9 percent, and pass-through entities. Therefore, the choice the marginal excess burden (expressed as a of business organization (regular corporation percentage of extra taxes raised) decreases taxed by the corporate income tax versus from 38 percent to 22 percent. The revenue- pass-through entity taxed solely at the indi- maximizing tax rate increases from 72.7 per- vidual level) might respond to the relative tax cent to 76.8 percent. rates on corporate versus individual income. This simple theoretical analysis shows For example, if the individual income tax therefore that, in addition to estimating the rate increases, some businesses taxed at the elasticity e, it is critical to analyze whether the source or destination of changes in 16 Net-of-tax corporate profits are generally taxed reported individual incomes is another tax again at the individual level when paid out as dividends base, either a concurrent one or in another to individual shareholders. Many OECD countries allevi- ate such double taxation of corporate profits by providing time period. Thus two additional param- tax credits or preferential tax treatment for dividends. If eters, in addition to the taxable income elas- profits are retained in the corporation, they increase the ticity e, are crucial in the estimation of the value of the company stock and those profits may, as in the United States, be taxed as realized capital gains when the tax revenue effects and marginal deadweight individual owners eventually sell the stock. In general, the individual level of taxation of corporate profits is lower than the ordinary individual tax on unincorporated businesses 15 We show below that s = 0.5 and t = 0.3 are realistic so that the combined tax on corporate profits and distrib- numbers to capture the shift from corporate to individual uted profits may be lower than the direct individual tax for taxable income following the Tax Reform Act of 1986. individuals subject to high marginal individual tax rates. 01_Saez.indd 11 2/27/12 3:49 PM 12 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) individual level may choose to incorporate Carroll and David Joulfaian 1997, and Saez where they would be subjected to the cor- 2004b among others). porate income tax instead.17 In that case, 2.2.2 Timing Responses the standard taxable income elasticity might be large and the individual income tax rev- If individuals anticipate that a tax increase enue consequences significant. However, will happen soon, such as when President corporate income tax revenue will increase Clinton was elected in late 1992 on a pro- and partially offset the loss in revenue on gram to raise top individual tax rates, which the individual side. It is possible to provide was indeed implemented in 1993, they have a micro-founded model capturing those incentives to accelerate taxable income real- effects.18 If businesses face heterogeneous izations before the tax change takes place.20 costs of switching organizational form (rep- As a result, reported taxable income just after resenting both transaction costs and nontax the reform will be lower than otherwise. In considerations) and the aggregate shifting that case, the tax increase has a positive fis- response to tax rate changes is smooth, then cal externality on the pre-reform period that marginal welfare analysis would still be appli- ought to be taken into account in a welfare cable. As a result, formula (9) is a sufficient analysis. statistic to derive the welfare costs of taxation As we will see below, this issue of reti- in that case.19 Estimating s and t empirically ming is particularly important in the case would require knowing the imputed corpo- of realized capital gains21 and stock-option rate profits of individual shareholders. exercises (Goolsbee 2000b) because indi- This issue was quite significant for analy- viduals can easily time the realization of such ses of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 because of income. Parcell (1995) and Sammartino and the sharp decline (and change in sign!) in the Weiner (1997) document the large shift of difference between the top personal and cor- taxable income into 1992 from 1993 (even porate tax rates, which created an incentive when excluding capital gains) in response to shift business income from the corpora- to the tax increase on high-income earners tion tax base to pass-through entities such as promised by President-elect Bill Clinton, partnerships or Subchapter S corporations, and enacted in early 1993. so that the business income shows up in the The labor supply literature started with individual income tax base (see appendix A a static framework and then developed a for a description of the 1986 tax reform). dynamic framework with intertemporal sub- This phenomenon was indeed widespread stitution to distinguish between responses immediately after the Tax Reform Act of to temporary versus permanent changes in 1986 (documented by Slemrod 1996, Robert wage rates (MaCurdy 1981). In this frame- work, differential responses arise because, and only because, the income effects of 17 Again, to the extent that dividends and capital gains temporary versus permanent changes are taxed, shareholders would not entirely escape the indi- vidual income tax. 18 Alvaredo and Saez (2009) develop such a model in 20 Anticipated tax decreases would have the opposite the case of the Spanish wealth tax, under which stock in effect. closely held companies is excluded from the wealth tax for 21 A well-known example is the U.S. Tax Reform Act of individuals who own at least 15 percent of the business and 1986, which increased the top tax rate on realized long- are substantially involved in management. term capital gains from 20 percent to 28 percent beginning 19 It is a reduced-form formula because a change in the in 1987, and generated a surge in capital gains realizations rules about business organization would in general change at the end of 1986 (Auerbach 1988; Burman, Clausing, and the behavioral elasticity. O’Hare 1994). 01_Saez.indd 12 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 13 differ.22 The ETI literature has focused As already noted, the ETI and MDWL on a simpler framework (usually) with no concepts are relevant for the optimal design income effects and within which intertem- of the tax and transfer system, because they poral issues cannot be modeled adequately. increase the economic cost of the higher mar- This is an important issue to keep in mind ginal tax rates needed to effect redistribu- when evaluating existing empirical studies tion. Importantly, though, they do not enter of the ETI; future research should develop directly into an evaluation of deficit-financed an intertemporal framework to account for tax cuts (or deficit-reducing tax increases). expected future tax rate changes, so as to This is because, with a fixed time pattern of distinguish responses to temporarily high, or government expenditure, tax cuts now must low, tax rates. Such a dynamic framework has eventually be offset by tax increases later. been developed for specific components of Ignoring the effects of one period’s tax rate taxable income such as realized capital gains on other periods’ taxable income, if the ETI (Burman and Randolph 1994) and charitable is relatively large a current tax cut will cause contributions (Bakija and Heim 2008). a relatively large increase in current taxable If current income tax rates increase, but income. Offsetting this, however, is the fact long-term future expected income tax rates that when the offsetting tax increases occur do not, individuals might decide to defer later, the high ETI (and there is no reason some of their incomes, for example, in the to think it will go up or down over time) form of future pension payments23 (deferred will generate relatively big decreases in tax- compensation) or future realized capital able income at that time. Accounting for the gains.24 In that case, a current tax increase intertemporal responses, both of the real and might have a positive fiscal externality in income-shifting variety, to time-varying tax future years; such a fiscal externality affects rate changes suggests that a deficit-financed the welfare cost of taxation as we described tax cut that, by definition, collects no revenue above. A similar issue applies whenever a in present value will cause deadweight loss change in tax rates affects business invest- by distorting the timing of taxable income ment decisions undertaken by individuals. flows. If, for example, a lower tax rate induces sole 2.2.3 Long-Term Responses proprietors or principals in pass-through entities to expand investment, the short-term One might expect short-term tax responses effect on taxable income may be n egative, to be larger than longer-term responses reflecting the deductible net expenses in the because people may be able to easily shift early years of an investment project. income between adjacent years without alter- ing real behavior. However, adjusting to a tax 22 In the labor supply literature, responses to tempo- change might take time (as individuals might rary wage rate changes are captured by the Frisch elastic- decide to change their career or educational ity, which is higher than the compensated elasticity with choices or businesses might change their respect to permanent changes. 23 In the United States, individual workers can elec- long-term investment decisions) and thus tively set aside a fraction of their earnings into pension the relative magnitude of the two responses plans (traditional IRAs and 401(k)s) or employers can pro- is theoretically ambiguous. The long-term vide increased retirement contributions at the expense of current compensation. In both cases, those pension contri- response is of most interest for policy mak- butions are taxed as income when the money is withdrawn. ing although, as we discuss below, the long- 24 For example, companies, on behalf of their share- term response is more difficult to identify holders, may decide to reduce current dividend payments and retain earnings that generate capital gains that are empirically. The empirical literature has pri- taxed later when the stock is sold. marily focused on short-term (one year) and 01_Saez.indd 13 2/27/12 3:49 PM 14 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) medium-term (up to five year) responses, the elasticity of reported income, but instead and is not able to convincingly identify very the elasticity of actual income. long-term responses. 2.2.5 Other Fiscal Externalities The issue of long-term responses is par- ticularly important in the case of capital Changes in reported incomes might also income, as capital income is the consequence have consequences for bases other than fed- of past savings and investment decisions. eral income taxes. An obvious example is For example, a higher top income tax rate the case of state income taxes in the United might discourage wealth accumulation or States. If formula (6) is applied to the fed- contribute to the dissipation of existing for- eral income tax only, it will not capture the tunes faster. Conversely, reductions in this externality on state income tax revenue (as rate might trigger an increase in the growth states in general use almost the same income rate of capital income for high-income indi- tax base as the federal government). Thus viduals. The new long-term wealth distribu- our original analysis should be based on the tion equilibrium might not be reached for combined federal and state income tax rates. decades or even generations, which makes it Changes in reported individual income due particularly difficult to estimate. Estimating to real changes in economic behavior (such the effects on capital accumulation would as reduced labor supply) can also have con- require developing a dynamic model of tax sequences for consumption taxes. In par- responses, which has not yet been developed ticular, a broad-based value added tax is in the context of the ETI literature. This economically equivalent to an income tax would be a promising way to connect the (with expensing) and therefore should also ETI literature to the macroeconomic litera- be included in the tax rate used for welfare ture on savings behavior. computations. Finally, fiscal externalities may also arise 2.2.4 Tax Evasion due to classical general equilibrium tax inci- Suppose that a tax increase leads to a dence effects. For example, a reduced tax higher level of tax evasion.25 In that case, rate on high incomes might stimulate labor there might be increases in taxes collected supply of workers in highly paid occupa- on evading taxpayers following audits. This tions, and hence could decrease their pre- increased audit-generated tax revenue is tax wage rate while reducing labor supply another form of a positive fiscal externality. and thus increasing pretax wage rates of In practice, most empirical studies are car- lower-paid occupations.26 Such incidence ried out using tax return data before audits effects are effectively transfers from some take place, and therefore do not fully capture factors of production (high-skilled labor in the revenue consequences. Chetty (2009b) our example) to other factors of production makes this point formally and shows that, (low-skilled labor). If different factors are under risk neutrality assumptions, at the taxed at different rates (due for example to margin the tax revenue lost due to increased tax evasion is exactly recouped (in expecta- 26 Such effects are extremely difficult to convincingly tion) by increased tax revenue collected at estimate empirically. Kubik (2004) attempts such an analy- audit. As a result, in that case the elasticity sis and finds that, controlling for occupation-specific time that matters for deadweight burden is not trends in wage rates, individuals in occupations that expe- rienced large decreases in their median marginal tax rates due to the Tax Reform Act of 1986 received lower pre-tax 25 Whether in theory one would expect this response is wages after 1986 as the number of workers and the hours not clear. See Yitzhaki (1974). worked in these professions increased. 01_Saez.indd 14 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 15 a progressive income tax), then those inci- not the extensive margin (home ownership) dence effects will have fiscal consequences. and that there is little evidence of externali- However, because those incidence effects ties along the intensive margin. Moreover, are transfers, in principle the government granting the existence of such externalities can readjust tax rates on each factor to undo does not imply that the implicit rate of sub- those incidence effects at no fiscal cost. sidy approximates marginal social benefit. Therefore, in a standard competitive model, Theoretically, suppose a fraction s of the incidence effects do not matter for the effi- taxable income response to a tax rate increase ciency analysis or for optimal tax design.27 dτ is due to higher expenditures on activities that create an externality with a social mar- 2.3 Classical Externalities ginal value of exactly t dollars per dollar of There are situations where individual additional expenditure. In that case, formula responses to taxation may involve clas- (8) applies by just substituting the alternative sical externalities. Two often mentioned tax base rate t with −1 multiplied by the per cases are charitable giving and mortgage dollar social marginal value of the external- interest payments for residential housing, ity. For example, in the extreme case where which in the United States and some other all the taxable income response comes from countries may be deductible from taxable tax expenditures (s = 1) with income before income, a tax treatment which is often jus- tax expenditures being unresponsive to tax tified on the grounds of classical exter- rates, and if t = τ (the social marginal value nalities. Contributions to charitable causes of tax expenditures externalities is equal to create positive externalities if contributions the income tax rate τ) then there is zero mar- increase the utility of the beneficiaries of the ginal excess burden from taxation as it is a nonprofit organizations. To the extent that pure Pigouvian tax.29 More generally, to the mortgage interest deductions increase home extent that the behavioral response to higher ownership, they can arguably create posi- tax rates generates some positive externali- tive externalities in neighborhoods. In both ties, formula (3) will overstate the marginal cases, however, there are reasons to be skep- efficiency cost of taxation. tical of the externality argument in practice. Because the bulk of items that are deduct- Using U.S. and French tax reforms, Fack and ible from taxable income in the United Landais (2010) show that the response of States—state and local income taxes, mort- charitable deductions to tax rates is concen- gage interest deductions, and charitable trated primarily along the avoidance margin giving—may generate fiscal or classical exter- (rather than the real contribution margin).28 nalities, the elasticity of a broader, prededuc- Glaeser and Shapiro (2003) examine the U.S. tion, concept of income (such as adjusted mortgage interest deduction and conclude gross income in the United States) is of inter- that it subsidizes housing ownership along est in addition to a taxable income elasticity. the intensive margin (size of the home) but That is why many conceptual and empirical analyses focus on adjusted gross income— which is not net of such deductible items— 27 Indeed, Diamond and Mirrlees (1971) showed that rather than taxable income. The elasticity of optimal tax formulas are the same in a model with fixed prices of factors (with no incidence effects) and in a model taxable income and the elasticity of a broader with variable prices (with incidence effects). measure of income may bracket the elasticity 28 There is a large earlier literature finding signifi- cant responses of charitable giving to individual marginal income tax rates. See, for example, Auten, Sieg, and 29 Saez (2004a) develops a simple optimal tax model to Clotfelter (2002). capture those effects. 01_Saez.indd 15 2/27/12 3:49 PM 16 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) applicable to welfare analysis. As discussed the tax base choice affects the taxable income above, we are skeptical that itemized deduc- elasticity. Thus, as Slemrod and Kopczuk tions in the U.S. tax code necessarily produce (2002) argue, the ETI can be thought of as a strong positive externalities. Therefore, we policy choice. The same logic applies to the will ignore this possibility and treat itemized enforcement of a given tax base, which can deduction responses to tax rates as efficiency particularly affect the behavioral response to costs in the following sections. tax rate changes of avoidance schemes and Classical externalities might also arise in evasion. agency models where executives set their To see this point, suppose that we estimate own pay by expending efforts to influence a large taxable income elasticity because the the board of directors.30 It is conceivable tax base includes many loopholes making that such pay-setting efforts depend on the it easy to shelter income from tax (we dis- level of the top income tax rate and would cuss in detail such examples using U.S. tax increase following a top tax rate cut. In reforms below). In the model of section 2.1, such a case, top executives’ compensation this suggests that a low tax rate is optimal. increases come at the expense of share- However, in a broader context, a much bet- holders’ returns, which produces a nega- ter policy may be to eliminate loopholes so tive externality.31 Such an externality would as to reduce the taxable income elasticity reduce the efficiency costs of taxation (as in and the deadweight burden of taxation.32 For that case correcting the externality dictates example, Gruber and Saez (2002) estimate a positive tax). that the taxable income elasticity for upper income earners is 0.57, leading to a revenue 2.4 Changes in the Tax Base Definition and maximizing rate of only 54 percent using for- Tax Erosion mula (7) with a = 1.5. However, they find a As pointed out by Slemrod (1995) and much lower elasticity of 0.17 for a broader Slemrod and Kopczuk (2002), how broadly income definition for upper incomes, imply- the tax base is defined affects the taxable ing that the revenue maximizing tax rate income elasticity. In their model, the more would be as high as 80 percent if the income tax deductions that are allowed, the higher tax base were broadened.33 will be the taxable income elasticity. This Consider a simple example that illustrates implies that the taxable income elasticity this argument. As in our basic model, indi- depends not only on individual p references viduals supply effort to earn income z. Now (as we posited in our basic model in section allow that individuals can, at some cost, shel- 2.1), but also on the tax structure. Therefore, ter part of their income z into another form that might receive preferable tax treatment. Let us denote w + y = z, where y is shel- 30 Under perfect information and competition, execu- tered income and w is unsheltered income. tives would not be able to set their pay at a different level Formally, individuals maximize a utility func- from their marginal product. In reality, the marginal prod- uct of top executives cannot be perfectly observed, which tion of the form u(c, z, y) that is decreasing creates scope for influencing pay, as discussed extensively in z (earning income requires effort) and y in Bebchuk and Fried (2004). 31 Such externalities would fit into the framework devel- (sheltering income is costly). Suppose we oped by Chetty (2009b). Following the analysis of Chetty and Saez (2010), such agency models produce an external- ity only if the pay contract is not second-best Pareto effi- 32 This possibility is developed in the context of an opti- cient, e.g., it is set by executives and large shareholders on mal linear income tax in Slemrod (1994). the board without taking into account the best interests of 33 Both scenarios assume away fiscal and classical exter- small shareholders outside the board. nalities in behavioral responses. 01_Saez.indd 16 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 17 start from a comprehensive tax base where z concerns, and externalities such as charitable is taxed at rate τ, so that c = (1 − τ) · z + E contributions, as discussed above.36 (E denotes a lump-sum transfer). In that case, sheltering income is costly and provides 3. Empirical Estimation and no tax benefit; individuals choose y = 0, and Identification Issues the welfare analysis proceeds as in section 3.1 where the relevant elasticity is the elas- 3.1 A Framework to Analyze the ticity of total income z with respect to 1 − τ. Identification Issues Now recognize that the tax base is eroded by excluding y from taxation. In that case, To assess the validity of the empirical c = (1 − τ) · w + y + E = (1 − τ) · z + methods used to estimate the ETI and to τ · y + E. Therefore, individuals will find it explicate the key identification issues, it profitable to shelter their income up to the is useful to consider a very basic model of point where τ · uc = uy . We can define the income reporting behavior. In year t, individ- indirect utility v(c′, w) = maxy u(c′ + y, w + ual i reports income zit and faces a marginal y, y) and the analysis of section 3.1 applies tax rate of τit = T′(zit ). Assume that reported using the elasticity of taxable income w with income zitresponds to marginal tax rates with respect to 1 − τ. Because w = z − y and elasticity e so that zit = z 0it · (1 − τit )e , where sheltered income y responds (positively) to z 0it is income reported when the marginal tax the tax rate τ, the elasticity of w is larger than rate is zero, which we call potential income.37 the elasticity of z and hence the deadweight Therefore, using logs, we have: burden of taxation per dollar raised is higher with the narrower base. Intuitively, giving (12) log zit = e · log(1 − τit ) + log z 0it . preferential treatment to y induces taxpayers to waste resources to shelter income y, which Note, in light of our previous preceding is pure deadweight burden. As a result, start- discussion, the assumptions that are embed- ing from the eroded tax base and introduc- ded in this simple model: (a) there are no ing a small tax dt > 0 on y actually reduces income effects on reported income (as vir- the deadweight burden from taxation, show- tual income E is excluded from specification ing that the eroded tax base is a suboptimal (12), (b) the response to tax rates is immedi- policy choice.34 ate and permanent (so that short-term and Therefore, comprehensive tax bases with long-term elasticities are identical), (c) the low elasticities are preferable to narrow elasticity e is constant over time and uniform bases with large elasticities. Of course this across individuals at all levels of income,38 (d) conclusion abstracts from possible legitimate individuals have perfect knowledge of the tax reasons for narrowing the tax base, such as structure and choose z it after they know the administrative simplicity (as in the model of Slemrod and Kopczuk 2002),35 redistributive 36 The public choice argument that narrow bases con- strain Leviathan governments would fall in that category, as a Leviathan government produces a negative externality. 34 This can be proved easily in a separable model with 37 A quasi-linear utility function of the form no income effects where u(c, z, y) = c − h1(z) − h2(y). u(c, z) = c − z0 (z/z0 )1+1/e /(1 + 1/e) generates such in- 35 In many practical cases, however, tax systems with a come response functions. comprehensive tax base (such as a value added tax) may be 38 This assumption can be relaxed in most cases, but it administratively simpler than a complex income tax with sometimes has important consequences for identification, many exemptions and a narrower base. as we discuss below. 01_Saez.indd 17 2/27/12 3:49 PM 18 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. L (March 2012) exact realization of potential income z 0it. We Suppose that all tax rates change at revisit these assumptions below. time t = 1 because of a tax reform. Using Even within the context of this simple repeated cross sections spanning the pre- and model, an OLS regression of log zit on post-reform periods, one can estimate the log (1 − τit) would not identify the elasticity following two-stage-least-squares regression: e in the presence of a graduated income tax schedule because τit is positively correlated (13) log zit = e · log(1 − τit ) + εit, with potential log-income log z 0it; this occurs because the marginal tax rate may increase using the post-reform indicator 1(t ≥ 1) as with realized income z. Therefore, it is nec- an instrument for log(1 − τit). This regres- essary to find instruments correlated with τit, sion identifies e if εit is uncorrelated with but uncorrelated with potential log-income, 1(t ≥ 1). In the context of our simple model log z 0it, to identify the elasticity e.39 The recent (12), this requires that potential log-incomes taxable income elasticity literature has used are not correlated with time. This assump- changes in the tax rate structure created tion is very unlikely to hold in practice, as real by tax reforms to obtain such instruments. economic growth creates a direct correlation Intuitively, in order to isolate the effects of between income and time. If more than two the net-of-tax rate, one would want to com- years of data are available, one could add a pare observed reported incomes after the tax linear trend β · t in (13) to control for secu- rate change to the incomes that would have lar growth. However, as growth rates vary been reported had the tax change not taken year-to-year due to macroeconomic business place. Obviously, the latter are not observed cycles, the elasticity estimate will be biased and must be estimated. We describe in this if economic growth happens to be differ- section the methods that have been pro- ent from year t = 0 to year t = 1 for reasons posed to estimate e and to address this iden- unrelated to the level of tax rates; in this case tification issue. the regression will ascribe to the tax change the impact of an unrelated, but coincident 3.2 Simple before and after Reform change in average incomes. Comparison In many contexts, however, tax reforms One simple approach uses reported affect subgroups of the population differen- incomes before a tax reform as a proxy for tially, and in some cases they leave tax rates reported incomes after the reform (had the essentially unchanged for most of the popu- reform not taken place). This simple differ- lation. For example, in the United States ence estimation method amounts to com- during the last three decades, the largest paring reported incomes before and after absolute changes in tax rates have taken the reform and attributing the change in place at the top of the income distribution, reported incomes to the changes in tax rates. with much smaller changes on average in the broad middle. In that context, one can use the group less (or not at all) affected by the tax change as a control and hence proxy 39 This issue arises in any context where the effective unobserved income changes in the affected price of the studied behavior depends on the marginal income tax rate, such as charitable contributions. In a case group (absent the tax reform) with changes such as this, though, a powerful instrument is the marginal in reported income in the control group. tax rate that would apply in the event of zero contributions, Such methods naturally lead to consider- a “first-dollar” marginal tax rate. When the studied behav- ior is taxable income, this instrument is not helpful, as it is ation of difference-in-differences estimation generally zero for everyone. methods discussed in section 3.4. 01_Saez.indd 18 2/27/12 3:49 PM Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz: The Elasticity of Taxable Income 19 3.3 Share Analysis incomes of the high-income individuals are indeed responsive to marginal tax rates. When the group affected by the tax Panel B of figure 1 shows the same income reform is relatively small, one can simply share and marginal tax rate series for the next normalize incomes of the group affected by 9 percent of highest-income tax filers (i.e., a tax change by the average income in the the top decile excluding the top 1 percent population to control for macroeconomic from panel A). Their marginal tax rate fol- growth. Indeed, recently the most dramatic lows a different pattern, first increasing from changes in U.S. marginal federal income tax 1960 to 1981 due primarily to bracket creep rates have taken place at the top percentile (as the tax system in this period was not of the income distribution. Therefore, and indexed for inflation), followed by a decline following Feenberg and Poterba (1993) and until 1988 and relative stability afterwards. Slemrod (1996), a natural measure of the In contrast to the top 1 percent, however, the evolution of top incomes relative to the aver- share of the next 9 percent in total income age is the change in the share of total income is very smooth and trends slightly upward reported by the top percentile.40 Panel A during the entire period. Most importantly,