ECN 104 Fall 2024 The Economic Approach (Chapters 1 & 2) PDF
Document Details
Uploaded by Deleted User
2024
Tags
Summary
These lecture notes provide an overview of the economic approach, covering optimization, equilibrium, and empiricism. They also explore economic questions and methods, using examples like the return on investment of university education and exploring concepts of scarcity and opportunity cost. This document is part of a fall 2024 economics course.
Full Transcript
The Economic Approach (Chapters 1 and 2) * ECN 104 - Fall 2024 September 6, 2024 1 / 71 Outline The Economic Approach First principle of economics: Optimization Second principle of economics: Equilibrium Third principle of economics: Empiricism...
The Economic Approach (Chapters 1 and 2) * ECN 104 - Fall 2024 September 6, 2024 1 / 71 Outline The Economic Approach First principle of economics: Optimization Second principle of economics: Equilibrium Third principle of economics: Empiricism Economic questions and economic methods Example: The Return on Investment of University Education Randomization 2 / 71 What is the economic approach? - A couple of definitions: - “Economics is the study of how societies use scarce resources to produce valuable commodities and distribute them among different people” (Samuelson and Nordhaus, 1995) 3 / 71 - A couple of definitions: - “Economics is the study of how societies use scarce resources to produce valuable commodities and distribute them among different people” (Samuelson and Nordhaus, 1995) - “Economics is the study of how agents choose to allocate scarce resources and how those choices affect society” (Acemoglu et al., 2022) 4 / 71 - Economists study human behaviour - Choice - not money - is the unifying feature of all the things that economists study - Economic agent = any group or individual that makes choices, such as consumers, firms, parents, politicians, etc. 5 / 71 Figure: Examples of economic agents 6 / 71 - Going back to our definition: “Economics is the study of how agents choose to allocate scarce resources and how those choices affect society” (Acemoglu et al., 2022) - What does it mean to be “scarce”? 7 / 71 - Scarce resources are things that people want, where the quantity that people want often exceeds the quantity that is available. - Scarcity is the situation of having unlimited wants in a world of limited resources. - Imagine a bowl of chocolates... 8 / 71 Positive Economics Describes what people actually do (some people take more than one and not everyone got a piece) Normative Economics Recommends what people, including society, ought to do (Each student should just take one so that everyone gets a piece) 9 / 71 Normative analysis and public policy Normative analysis also generates advice to society in general Figure: Examples of economic agents 10 / 71 Microeconomics The study of how individuals, firms, and governments make choices Macroeconomics The study of the whole economy 11 / 71 How would you classify the following: - The inflation rate - The market for coal-fired electricity generation - Environment - Understanding how sleep affects students’ grades - The growth rate of a country’s total economic output 12 / 71 - These definitions are silent about what the “economic approach” is. - What kind of behaviour drives the usage of the scarce resources? The production of these valuable commodities? Who gets to consume what? 13 / 71 - What is the economic approach? - The Economic Approach: ”The combined assumptions of maximizing behaviour, market equilibrium, and stable preferences, used relentlessly and unflinchingly, from the heart of the economic approach as I see it.” (Becker 1976, p.5) - The economic approach consists of four components: 1. Stable preferences 2. Optimization 3. (Market) equilibrium 4. Empiricism 14 / 71 Breadth of the economic approach - The economic approach is not limited to the market sector (market for goods/services, stock market, unemployment, among others) - Also useful in the analysis of the non-market sector (discrimination, human capital, marriage, fertility, crime, among others) - The economic approach applies uniformly to ALL areas of human behaviour 15 / 71 A powerful tool - Well known/obvious results of this approach: - Downward sloping demand curve - Upward sloping supply curve - Why? - As prices (i.e., incentives) change, buyers/sellers re-optimize 16 / 71 - Not-so obvious results of this approach: - Not only prices, but shadow prices - When the “cost” of committing a crime increases (i.e., shadow prices of crime decreases) supply of crime goes down - When the “cruise time” for cab drivers goes down, supply of cab-rides increases (Becker, 1976) - When the shadow prices of children increases, demand for children decreases 17 / 71 Source: World Bank 18 / 71 Why is this approach such a powerful tool? The economic approach: 1. Stable preferences 2. Optimization 3. (Market) equilibrium 4. Empiricism 19 / 71 Three principles of economics: 1. Optimization = making the best choice possible with given information 2. (Market) equilibrium = when everyone is optimizing; no one would be better off with a different choice 3. Empiricism = using data to figure out answers to interesting questions 20 / 71 First principle of economics: Optimization - Economists believe that people optimize - In other words, based on benefits (from preferences/priorities) and costs (constraints) people make the best feasible choice - People don’t always succeed in optimizing - we are not calculating machines - but people generally try to optimize 21 / 71 Discussion: Optimizing your time As a student, you have to determine how to allocate your time to studying, socializing, and sleeping in a 24 hour day. How much time to you dedicate to each activity? You must allocate at least 4 hours to sleeping. Discuss in groups! - NOTE: Think about trade-offs, your preferences, and constraints (i.e., you are constrained with the number of hours in the day, and having a minimum of 4 hours of sleep). - What are the benefits and costs of studying, socializing, and sleeping? 22 / 71 First principle of economics: Optimization - Benefits - Benefits depend on preferences or priorities - So benefits can include your preference for fairness, equity (not just money) - But economists have no say about your preferences or priorities - We are not here to tell you what to like or dislike - But based on what you like, and the resources you have, economists can tell what your optimal choice should be 23 / 71 First principle of economics: Optimization - Costs - Economists think differently about costs - Consider Facebook - by early 2023, 2.9 billion users spent over 1.5 billion hours per day on Facebook - Clearly people love Facebook, but why? 24 / 71 - If you asked Facebook users why they use it, they might say... - It’s fun - Easy way to stay connected to family and friends - It’s accessible and convenient - It’s free - BUT, is Facebook really free? 25 / 71 Opportunity costs Even if you don’t pay Facebook to use it, what is the value of the time of its users? - Let’s consider wages: - $9 minimum wage in high-income countries - $1 minimum wage in low-income countries - Half of Facebook’s users are in low-income countries: weighted average = 0.5($9) + 0.5($1) = $5 - We assume a $5/hour opportunity cost of using Facebook 26 / 71 Opportunity cost - All choices have opportunity cost (an alternative option) - Sometimes, people find it hard to consider the opportunity costs of a choice (particularly if it is non-monetary) - Get used to assessing monetary value to opportunity cost 27 / 71 - So Facebook has its costs - Are you spending the optimal amount of time on Facebook? - That’s your decision! - You probably know the benefits of using Facebook (try hard to put some monetary value to it) - But using Facebook because it’s free should NOT be the reason - Make sure you consider the opportunity cost 28 / 71 Optimization, trade-offs, and budget constraints What is the optimal level of crime? - Pollution? Poverty? - Spending more money on crime reduction means less money on education, social programs, etc. - Also, reducing the last bit of crime is very costly - Trade off! Again, benefits vs. costs! 29 / 71 Optimization: benefits vs. costs - Optimization is about balancing out benefits and costs - Cost-benefit analysis - All optimization problems involve trade-offs - Trade-offs arise when some benefits must be given up in order to gain others 30 / 71 - A budget constraint is the set of things that a person can choose to do (or buy) without breaking her budget - Economists use budget constraints to describe trade-offs - Evaluating trade-offs can be difficult, because so many options are under consideration - Again, opportunity cost is the best alternative use of a resource - Economists sometimes try to put a monetary value on oportunity cost (e.g., our FB example) 31 / 71 Something to ponder... - Are Google services free? - Google (i.e., Alphabet) provides a number of services for free (up to a certain extent) - Q1: Are they really free? - These services are costly to provide for Google - Q2: So, is Google being irrational? 32 / 71 - It is not entirely free because we give up our privacy - Google is in the business of selling ads - So Google is clearly optimizing - Optimization tells us that we should weigh both the benefits and costs when making a decision 33 / 71 Three principles of economics: 1. Optimization 2. (Market) equilibrium 3. Empiricism 34 / 71 Second principle of economics: Equilibrium Equilibrium: A situation where no one benefits by changing his/her behaviour 35 / 71 Second principle of economics: Equilibrium Equilibrium: A situation where no one benefits by changing his/her behaviour 36 / 71 Why do we care about equilibrium? - Imagine an environment (or situation, market) where lots of optimizing individuals interact - What will happen in that environment? - It will move towards an equilibrium - The economic model will have predictive power about this equilibrium - Potentially allow “changes” in the environment 37 / 71 Is equilibrium always great? - But equilibrium is not always “nice” - E.g., free-riding 38 / 71 The economic approach in practice - Given the situation/environment you want to analyze: - Who are the decision makers, and what are their preferences? What incentives do they face? - Convince yourselves that these decision makers will pursue optimizing behaviour! - If everybody pursues optimizing behaviour, what is the likely equilibrium? - Do you want to change this environment so that the new equilibrium is a “better one” for you? 39 / 71 Three principles of economics: 1. Optimization 2. (Market) equilibrium 3. Empiricism 40 / 71 Third principle of economics: Empiricism - We are not just armchair economists! - We don’t just ponder theoretically and hypotheticallly about the questions that interest us 41 / 71 - We follow the scientific method - We develop theoretical models of the question - These models will have predictions - We test them with data: we evaluate the match between the models and the data - And we are rigorous, and careful with the data 42 / 71 Economic questions and economic methods Economic questions - Usually people are surprised by the broad range of issues that the economic approach can address - People generally associate “economics” with finance, stock market, the macro economy, money, etc. - Economists are interested in human behaviour, human decisions in general - And we can always apply the economic approach 43 / 71 - Think about the decision made by students to attend university. Why do they go to university? - Like any optimization problem you have to consider benefits and costs - Clearly there are costs: tuition + opportunity cost of time - You could be spending the money and time elsewhere - This is clearly an important decision - We can build economic models to explain your behaviour - Development of human capital? - Asymmetry in information: signalling? 44 / 71 Types of questions: - Health: - Will PR campaigns around the benefits of having a large family increase fertility? - Organizations: - Charitable organizations want to know cost effective ways of fundraising. IF we match donations $1 per $1, how much more can we fundraise? How about $2 per $1? $0.5 per $1? 45 / 71 - Human capital: - Should we spend more money on early childhood education or on high school students to increase high school graduation rate? - Can vouchers for private schools (i.e., use of public money for private schools) increase student achievement while reducing costs? - These are questions involving CAUSE AND EFFECT 46 / 71 A question and decision you have thought about and made already: - Is university worth it? Should you go to university? - It is a big investment - About $6,800 at universities for domestic students (2022/2023) - Costs of college, or vocational school - Plus, opportunity cost of time - So this is a very important decision made by high school students, and as economists we are really interested in understanding such behaviour/decisions Q: Does going to university lead to higher earnings? 47 / 71 Discuss: How would you go about answering the question does going to university lead to higher earnings? 48 / 71 Economic methods - How do we go about answering this question? - Use anecdotes? - My older cousins who have gone to college are doing really well financially! - Use causal observations? - Look at the most successful and rich entrepreneurs in Tech. Bill Gates, Steve Jobs, Mark Zuckerberg. - They are all college drop outs. Surely going to college doesn’t pay off. - Use intuition? - You have to be smart to go to university. You also must learn something useful there. Surely your annual earnings will increase after graduation! 49 / 71 - We are not armchair economists - We don’t just ponder theoretically and hypothetically about the questions that interest us - We follow the scientific method - We develop models of the questions - These models will have predictions - We test them with data: we evaluate the match between the models and the data - Example: Environmental exposure - Does increased exposure to large, unanticipated natural disasters affect how people vote for environmental legislation? - We can think about models for this and test it - E.g., increased exposure by 2 disasters may affect voting more than 1 disaster 50 / 71 Is university worth it? - Do university graduates have higher salaries? - Q: How would you answer this using data? - The natural approach for an empirically minded person is to gather mounds and mounds of data - This person might compare the salaries of those who have graduated from university to those who have not graduated from university 51 / 71 For example, something like this: It looks like university really pays off! Four years of an investment leading to higher earning throughout your working years! 52 / 71 Is university worth it? In this exercise, we are indeed looking at the correlation between annual earnings and college attendance. 53 / 71 For example, with a richer data set at the individual level we might observe something like this: Here, we see a positive correlation 54 / 71 - But does correlation imply causation? - Not necessarily! - Do ice creams cause drowning? 55 / 71 - Do ice creams cause drowning? - Of course not! What’s going on? - There is something that we have not considered here (e.g., hot weather, high temperature) that’s causing both! - Omitted variable - So we need to be careful when looking at just correlation - Correlation does not imply causation! 56 / 71 - Let’s say, we are confident about the causation - So lets think carefully about what’s behind these two numbers: these are average earnings 57 / 71 - Q: If you compared the high school graduates (i=1,2,...,10) to college graduate (i=11, 12,...,20), what differences would you find? - Of course, we already know about the difference in college degree - But what about other observable variables? - Let’s dig in deeper 58 / 71 - We might find out something that looks like... - For high school graduates (i=1,2,...,10): - Lower GPA, parents with lower income, lower teacher quality, etc. - Of course, on average - For college graduates (i=11,12,...,20): - Higher GPA, parents with higher income, higher teacher quality, etc. - Again, on average 59 / 71 First, the graph looks like the following: 60 / 71 But in reality... 61 / 71 - Let’s think about what this selection bias does to how we interpret the data - Some of the increased earning might not be because of college, but... - Better skills acquired before college - So we are likely overestimating the return to college! 62 / 71 - Then what can we do? - College data on GPA, income of parents, quality of teachers, etc. - Isolate the effect of college by looking at students who have similar GPA, parent income, teacher quality, etc. 63 / 71 - In other words, we are “controlling” for those observable variables! - Then, are we done? - What about other potential observable variables? Quality of schools; peer effects from friends; others? - What about unobservable variables that are really hard to measure: student motivation? And others that we are not even aware of. 64 / 71 - Economists (and other scientists) have developed statistical tools to overcome these problems - Highlights the power of experiments 65 / 71 Summary - But collecting data is not always easy - And much worse when we cannot observe the variables; the unobserved confounders - In this context, we want to introduce experiments - How can experiments help us solve the problems we just summarized? 66 / 71 Randomization-Random assignment - Say I shuffle 1,000 decks of playing cards into one pile (i.e., 52,000 cards) - I will successively draw cards from the pile - Each time I draw a card, I toss a fair coin. If it is heads, I placed the card in pile A. If it is tails, I placed it in pile B. - I do this until I have no cards left in the pile. 67 / 71 What does randomization give us? - Q: How many red cards in pile A? - Q: How many even cards in pile A? - How would your answers change if I substitute “A” or “B”? - They won’t change! - No matter which ’variable’ we look at, they are likely to be balanced across the two piles - Balanced on expectation 68 / 71 - Take the entire population of high school students in Toronto - For each one of them, we toss a coin: if heads, the student is placed in group A. If tails, in group B. - When I look at average GPA, parents income, teacher quality across the two groups, what will I find? - They will be balanced! 69 / 71 - As a thought experiment only...think about an experiment in Toronto schools - What if I send the students in group A to college and the students in group B end their education at grade 12? - And then, after 12-13 years, I compared the average annual earnings of both groups? - The selection bias is gone! - I don’t have to worry about the unobserved confounders because whichever they are they are balanced across the two groups! - No selection bias - Randomization into control and treatment gives us the appropriate counterfactual (group for comparison) 70 / 71 Next class: Optimization 71 / 71