Economic Efficiency and Surplus (2015) PDF
Document Details
Uploaded by CleanestMeter
HSLU Hochschule Luzern
2015
Tags
Summary
This document covers economic efficiency and models for calculating surplus, focusing on consumer and producer surpluses.
Full Transcript
Economics Lucerne School of Business Professor Gour Saraff Economic surplus and efficiency Page 1 CHAPTER CHAPTER 4 Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and...
Economics Lucerne School of Business Professor Gour Saraff Economic surplus and efficiency Page 1 CHAPTER CHAPTER 4 Economic Efficiency, Government Price Setting, and Taxes Chapter Outline and Learning Objectives 4.1 Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus 4.2 The Efficiency of Competitive Markets 4.3 Government Intervention in the Market: Price Floors and Price Ceilings 4.4 The Economic Impact of Taxes Appendix: Quantitative Demand and Supply Analysis © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 2 Should the Government Control Apartment Rents? Rent control puts a legal limit on the rent that landlords can charge for an apartment. Since rent-controlled rents are usually far below market rents, it seems clear that this doesn’t make landlords better off. Does it make tenants better off? Would you prefer to look for an apartment in a city with or without rent control? © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 3 Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus 4.1 LEARNING OBJECTIVE Distinguish between the concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 4 Consumer and Producer Surplus Surplus (noun): Something that remains above what is used or needed Economists use the idea of “surplus” to refer to the benefit that people derive from engaging in market transactions. Consumer surplus is the difference between the highest price a consumer is willing to pay for a good or service and the actual price the consumer receives. Producer surplus is the difference between the lowest price a firm would be willing to accept for a good or service and the price it actually receives. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 5 Deriving the Demand Curve for Chai Tea Suppose four people are each interested in buying a cup of chai tea. We can characterize them by the highest price they are willing to pay. At prices above $6, no chai tea will be sold. Figure 4.1 Deriving the demand At $6, one cup will be curve for chai tea sold, etc. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 6 How Much Benefit Will Chai Tea Drinkers Receive? How much benefit do the potential tea consumers derive from this market? That depends on the price and their marginal benefit, the additional benefit to a consumer from consuming one more unit of a good or service. If the price is low, many of the consumers benefit. If the price is high, few (if any) of the consumers Figure 4.1 Deriving the demand curve for chai tea benefit. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 7 Consumer Surplus at a Price of $3.50 If the price of tea is $3.50 per cup, Theresa, Tom, and Terri will buy a cup. Theresa was willing to pay $6.00; a cup of chai tea is “worth” $6.00 to her. She got it for $3.50, so she derives a net benefit of $6.00 – $3.50 = $2.50. Area A represents this net benefit, and is known as Theresa’s consumer surplus Figure 4.2a Measuring consumer surplus in the chai tea market. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 8 Consumer Surplus at a Price of $3.50—continued Tom and Terri also obtain consumer surplus, equal to $1.50 (area B) and $0.50 (area C). The sum of the areas of rectangles A, B, and C is called the consumer surplus in the chai tea market. This area can be described as the area below the demand curve, above the price that consumers pay. Figure 4.2a Measuring consumer surplus © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 9 Consumer Surplus If Price Falls to $3.00 If the price falls to $3.00, Theresa, Tom, and Terri each gain an additional $0.50 of consumer surplus. Tim is indifferent between buying the cup or not; his well- being is the same either way. The overall consumer surplus remains the area below the demand curve, above the (new) price. Figure 4.2b Measuring consumer surplus © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 10 Total Consumer Surplus in the Market for Chai Tea The market for chai tea is larger than just our four consumers. With many consumers, the market demand curve looks “normal”: a straight line. Consumer surplus in this market is defined in just the same way: the area below the demand curve, above price. The graph shows consumer surplus if price is $2.00. Figure 4.3 Total consumer surplus in the market for chai tea © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 11 Making the Consumer Surplus from Broadband Internet Connection Having access to a broadband internet connection is beneficial for consumers. We can measure just how beneficial it is by estimating the consumer surplus derived in the market. What would we need to know in order to do this? The demand curve for broadband internet service The price of broadband internet service © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 12 Making the CS from Broadband Internet—continued Connection In 2006, the average price for broadband internet service was $36 per month. Economists Shane Greenstein and Ryan McDevitt estimated the demand curve for broadband internet service, shown on the right. CS = Area of shaded triangle = ½ (47 – 0) ($73.89 – $36) = $890.4 million per month © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 13 Producer Surplus Producer surplus can be thought of in much the same way as consumer surplus. Producer surplus: The difference between the lowest price a firm would accept for a good or service and the price it actually receives. What is the lowest price a firm would accept for a good or service? The marginal cost of producing that good or service. Marginal cost: the additional cost to a firm of producing one more unit of a good or service. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 14 Measuring Producer Surplus (Single Firm) Heavenly Tea is a (very small) producer of chai tea. When the market price of tea is $2.00, Heavenly Tea receives producer surplus of $0.75 on the first cup (the area of rectangle A), $0.50 on the second cup (rectangle B), and $0.25 on the third cup (rectangle C). Figure 4.4a Measuring producer surplus © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 15 Measuring Producer Surplus (Entire Market) The total amount of producer surplus tea sellers receive from selling chai tea can be calculated by adding up for the entire market the producer surplus received on each cup sold. Total producer surplus is equal to the area above the supply curve and below the market Figure 4.4b Measuring producer price of $2.00. surplus © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 16 What Consumer and Producer Surplus Measure Consumer surplus measures the net benefit to consumers from participating in a market rather than the total benefit. Consumer surplus in a market is equal to the total benefit received by consumers minus the total amount they must pay to buy the good or service. Similarly, producer surplus measures the net benefit received by producers from participating in a market. Producer surplus in a market is equal to the total amount firms receive from consumers minus the cost of producing the good or service. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 17 The Efficiency of Competitive Markets 4.2 LEARNING OBJECTIVE Understand the concept of economic efficiency. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 18 How Much Output is Efficient? We can think about efficiency in a market in two ways: 1. A market is efficient if all trades take place where the marginal benefit exceeds the marginal cost, and no other trades take place. 2. A market is efficient if it maximizes the sum of consumer and producer surplus (i.e. the total net benefit to consumers and firms), known as the economic surplus. Economic efficiency: A market outcome in which the marginal benefit to consumers of the last unit produced is equal to its marginal cost of production and in which the sum of consumer and producer surplus is at a maximum. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 19 The Efficiency of Competitive Equilibrium Recall that the demand curve describes the marginal benefit of each additional cup of tea, while the supply curve describes the marginal cost of each additional cup of tea. If the quantity is too low, the value to consumers of the next unit exceeds Figure 4.5 Marginal benefit equals marginal cost the cost to producers. only at competitive equilibrium If the quantity is too high, the cost to producers of the last unit is greater than the value consumers derive from it. Only at the competitive equilibrium is the last unit valued by consumers and producers equally—economic efficiency. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 20 The Efficiency of Competitive Equilibrium—Surplus The figure shows the economic surplus (the sum of consumer and producer surplus) in the market for chai tea. At the competitive equilibrium quantity, the economic surplus is maximized. Figure 4.6 Economic surplus equals the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus Our two concepts of economic efficiency result in the same level of output! © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 21 Economic Surplus If the Market is Not in Equilibrium Figure 4.7 When a market is not in equilibrium, there is a deadweight loss When the price of chai tea is $2.20 instead of $2.00, consumer surplus declines from an amount equal to the sum of areas A, B, and C to just area A. Producer surplus increases from the sum of areas D and E to the sum of areas B and D. Economic surplus decreases by the sum of areas C and E. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 22 Deadweight Loss Resulting From Non-Equilibrium Quantity Figure 4.7 When a market is not in equilibrium, there is a deadweight loss The reduction in economic surplus resulting from a market not being in competitive equilibrium is known as deadweight loss. Deadweight loss can be thought of as the amount of inefficiency in a market. In competitive equilibrium, deadweight loss is zero. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 23 Government Intervention in the Market: Price Floors and Price Ceilings 4.3 LEARNING OBJECTIVE Explain the economic effect of government-imposed price floors and price ceilings. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 24 Price Ceilings and Price Floors One option a government has for affecting a market is the imposition of a price ceiling or a price floor. Price ceiling: A legally determined maximum price that sellers can charge. Price floor: A legally determined minimum price that sellers may receive. Price ceilings and floors in the USA are uncommon, but include: Minimum wages Rent controls Agricultural price controls © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 25 Price Floors: Agricultural Price Supports The equilibrium price in the market for wheat is $3.00 per bushel; 2.0 billion bushels are traded at this price. If wheat farmers convince the government to impose a price floor of $3.50 per bushel, quantity traded falls to 1.8 billion. Area A is the surplus transferred from consumers to producers. Figure 4.8 The economic effect of Economic surplus is reduced by a price floor in the area B + C, the deadweight loss. wheat market © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 26 Price Floors: It Gets Worse… Unfortunately, the situation may be even worse. If farmers do not realize they will not be able to sell all their wheat, they will produce 2.2 billion bushels. This results in a surplus, or excess supply, of 400 million bushels of wheat. Figure 4.8 The economic effect of a price floor in the wheat market © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 27 Making the Price Floors in Labor Markets Connection Supporters of the minimum wage see it as a way of raising the incomes of low- skilled workers. Opponents argue that it results in fewer jobs and imposes large costs on small businesses. Assuming the minimum wage does decrease employment, it must result in a deadweight loss for society. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 28 Price Ceilings: Rent Controls Without rent control, the equilibrium rent is $2,500 per month. At that price, 2,000,000 apartments would be rented. If the government imposes a rent ceiling of $1,500, the quantity of apartments supplied falls to 1,900,000, and the quantity of apartments demanded increases to 2,100,000, resulting in a shortage of Figure 4.9 The economic effect of a rent ceiling 200,000 apartments. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 29 Price Ceilings: the Effect of Rent Controls Producer surplus equal to the area of the blue rectangle A is transferred from landlords to renters. There is a deadweight loss equal to the areas of yellow triangles B and C. This deadweight loss corresponds to the surplus that would have been derived from apartments that are no longer rented. Figure 4.9 The economic effect of a rent ceiling © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 30 Black Markets and Peer-to-Peer Sites The shortage of apartments may lead to a black market – a market in which buying and selling take place at prices that violate government price regulations. Alternatively, landlords might switch from long-term to short-term rentals in order to avoid rent-controls; peer-to-peer rental sites such as Airbnb have facilitated this. These markets may alleviate some of the deadweight loss by allowing additional apartments to be rented; but buyers and sellers lose valuable legal protections. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 31 The Results of Government Price Controls It is clear that when a government imposes price controls, Some people are made better off, Some people are made worse off, and The economy generally suffers, as deadweight loss will generally occur. Economists seldom recommend price controls, with the possible exception of minimum wage laws. Why minimum wage laws? Price controls might be justified if there are strong equity effects to override the efficiency loss. The people benefitting from minimum wage laws are generally poor. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 32 The Economic Impact of Taxes 4.4 LEARNING OBJECTIVE Analyze the economic impact of taxes. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 33 Taxes Taxes are the most important method by which governments fund their activities. We will concentrate on per-unit taxes: taxes assessed as a particular dollar amount on the sale of a good or service, as opposed to a percentage tax. Example: The US Federal government imposes a 18.4 cents per gallon tax on gasoline sales, as of 2013. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 34 The Effect of a Tax on Cigarettes Without the tax, market equilibrium occurs at point A. The equilibrium price of cigarettes is $5.00 per pack, and 4 billion packs of cigarettes are sold per year. A $1.00-per-pack tax on cigarettes will cause the supply curve for cigarettes to shift up by $1.00, from S1 Figure 4.10 The effect of a tax on the to S2. market for cigarettes The new equilibrium occurs at point B. The price of cigarettes will increase by $0.90, to $5.90 per pack, and the quantity sold will fall to 3.7 billion packs. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 35 What Just Happened to the Supply Curve? The supply curve shifted up by $1.00, the amount of the tax. If firms were willing to sell 4 billion packs at a price of $5.00 before the tax, the price needs to be exactly $1.00 higher in order to convince them to still sell 4 billion packs. Figure 4.10 The effect of a tax on the market for cigarettes This is because firms’ marginal costs effectively increased by $1.00 per unit. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 36 The Effect of a Tax on Cigarettes The tax increases the price paid by consumers to $5.90 per pack. Producers receive a price of $5.90 per pack (point B), but after paying the $1.00 tax, they are left with $4.90 (point C). The government will receive tax revenue equal to the Figure 4.10 The effect of a tax on the green-shaded box. market for cigarettes Some consumer surplus and some producer surplus will become tax revenue for the government, and some will become deadweight loss, shown by the yellow-shaded area. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 37 Tax Incidence on a Demand and Supply Graph With no tax on gasoline, the price would be $3.50 per gallon, and 144 billion gallons of gasoline would be sold each year. A 10-cents-per-gallon excise tax shifts up the supply curve from S1 to S2. The price consumers pay rises from $3.50 to $3.58. The price sellers receive falls from $3.50 to $3.48. Therefore, consumers pay 8 cents of the 10-cents-per- Figure 4.11 The incidence of a tax on gasoline gallon tax on gasoline, and sellers pay 2 cents. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 38 Tax Incidence: Who Actually Pays for a Tax? In the market for gasoline, the buyers effectively paid 80% of the 10- cents-per-gallon tax, and sellers paid 20%. This is referred to as the tax incidence: the actual division of the burden of a tax between buyers and sellers in a market. What determines this tax incidence? As we will see on the next slide, the answer is not “whoever has the legal obligation to pay the tax…” © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 39 What Does Determine the Tax Incidence? The incidence of the tax is determined by the relative slopes of the demand and supply curves. A steep demand curve means that buyers do not change how much they buy when the price changes; this results in them taking on much of the burden of the tax. If the demand curve were shallower, buyers would change how much they bought a lot in response to a price change. Then they could not be forced to accept as much of the burden of the tax. Similar analysis applies for sellers. © 2015 Pearson Education, Inc. 40 30.10.2024 Seite 41