Purchasing Power Parity And Floating Exchange Rate Experience PDF
Document Details
Uploaded by SelectiveBanshee
Prof. F. Klaassen
Tags
Related
Summary
This document is a lecture or presentation on Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) and its application in understanding exchange rate determination. It covers the theoretical underpinnings of PPP, empirical evidence including the Big Mac index, and various factors that cause deviations from PPP.
Full Transcript
Purchasing Power Parity and Floating Exchange Rate Experience Pilbeam, chapter 6 Prof. F. Klaassen What you will learn Goods prices matter for the exchange rate in the long run: higher inflation in H vs. F comes with depreciation of H currency vs. F. How g...
Purchasing Power Parity and Floating Exchange Rate Experience Pilbeam, chapter 6 Prof. F. Klaassen What you will learn Goods prices matter for the exchange rate in the long run: higher inflation in H vs. F comes with depreciation of H currency vs. F. How good is P/P* at forecasting S? Short run: terribly bad Long run: some evidence that P/P* is useful (PPP makes sense). High labor productivity in producing traded goods causes high aggregate price levels (Balassa-Samuelson): Useful to explain: rich countries have higher price levels: deviation from PPP. 2/28 Motivation Earlier chapters: S matters for BoP and policy Important to know how S comes about. See chapters 6-8: theories on exchange rate determination. (Note: chapters 6-8 concern a floating exchange rate, obviously.) 3/28 Theories of exch. rate determination Chapter 6 Exch. rate determined by goods market purchasing power parity (PPP) Empirical testing of PPP incomplete explanation of exchange rate. Chapter 7 Add money market and bond market monetary models Two main theories: flexible and sticky prices Assumption: domestic (H) and foreign (F) bonds are perfect substitutes Empirical testing substitutability assumption is sometimes rejected. Chapter 8 Allow for imperfect substitutability of H&F bonds (risk premium). 4 Idea behind PPP: law of one price Law of one price Arbitrage equalizes goods prices internationally Need to compare prices internationally: use exchange rate to convert foreign price into domestic currency For good g: Pg = S Pg*: “Law of one price” (LOP). Equilibrium restoration: if Pg > S Pg*, then only demand F good more demand F currency S. 6 Example: Big Mac parity The Economist has collected Big Mac prices around the world Compute Big Mac exchange rate, the rate that equalizes Big Mac prices: SBM=PBM/P*BM: a reference/equilibrium exchange rate. Useful for measuring undervaluation of domestic currency: (S-SBM)/SBM Positive if S>SBM, as should be for undervaluation of H currency. Examples (more in tutorial): July 2023 – S = 0.91 €/$ – SBM = €5.28/$5.58 = 0.95 €/$ Undervaluation of euro is -4% (i.e., overvaluation of 4%). 7/28 Big Mac parity 1999-2011 Euro per dollar exchange rate and Big Mac rate (red) 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 14% 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 01-1999 01-2001 01-2003 01-2005 01-2007 01-2009 01-2011 In 2nd half: actual price of a dollar is lower than Big Mac reference price Dollar is undervalued (euro is overvalued). 8/28 Data sources: Datastream (blue) and The Economist (red) Using Big Macs for exchange rate? Critique on Big Mac parity: Prices are distorted by taxes and price discrimination There exist reasons for price differences Trade in Big Macs is hampered by transportation costs Arbitrage mechanism does not work well Prices are not equalized perfectly. True, but red Big Mac line isn’t that bad; if Big Mac rate were unrelated to S, the line could have been around 10, say Big Mac rate is truly related to S, but we cannot say how strong the relation is. 9/28 Comparing Big Mac to... iPod: arbitrage works better iPod exchange rate is SiPod=PiPod/P*iPod. Euro/dollar exch. rate, Big Mac (red) and iPod rates iPod touch, 29-1-2011: 1.3 €229 in Germany 1.2 $229 in US SiPod=1 €/$. 1.1 1 0.9 27% 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 01-1999 01-2001 01-2003 01-2005 01-2007 01-2009 01-2011 Euro overvaluation of 27%: in line with Big Mac message. 10/28 Data sources: Datastream (blue) and The Economist (red) PPP and its variants Timers From LOP to PPP If LOP holds for all g in the economy [i.e., Pg = S Pg*], then for the bundle of all g, with aggregate prices P and P*: P = S P*: this is PPP Purchasing power of €1 is the same in H and F, 1/P resp. 1/(SP*). Other interpretation: S=P/P*: exchange rate equals the ratio of H and F price levels. Note: S=P/P* is not how the exchange rate is defined; it is just the value according to the PPP theory [definition of S is the number of home currency units per unit of foreign currency, so has nothing to do with goods prices P&P*] PPP does not imply LOP, as deviations from LOP for some goods may offset each other when aggregating, so that PPP can still hold. 12 PPP is old idea: Cassell (1920s) or even Ricardo (1810s). According to PPP Absolute and relative PPP (1/2) PPP concept of previous slide is actually absolute PPP: P = S P*. Problem: P and P* are not published in levels, only in index form (P/P0); think of CPI Absolute PPP cannot be verified Need additional PPP concept. 14/28 Absolute and relative PPP (2/2) Alternative: consider changes over time, i.e., relative PPP: dP/P = dS/S + dP*/P*. Note: dP/P is observed, since dP/P=d(P/P0)/(P/P0): no need to know price levels absolute-PPP problem has been avoided. Other interpretation: dS/S = dP/P – dP*/P*: depreciation is excess inflation in H over F Higher inflation comes together with depreciation. 15 Relations between abs. and rel. PPP Pilbeam uses several other PPP formulas; here they are collected. Switch to logs for convenience: Absolute PPP: p=s+p*, where p=log(P), s=log(S) Relative PPP: dp=ds+dp*. Encompassing form: p = s + p* + c (c is a constant) Absolute PPP: c=0 Relative PPP: c is unrestricted. Real exchange rate (in logs) is sr = s+p*-p: Absolute PPP: sr=0 Relative PPP: sr is unrestricted constant. If abs. PPP holds, then rel. holds too: abs. is more restrictive than rel. 16/28 Is difference absolute vs. relative PPP clear? PPP in reality Timers Evidence on long-run relative PPP 82 countries vs. US Relative PPP is useful in long run. Source: Feenstra and Taylor: International Economics, first edition Loooong run: 200 years of CPIUS vs. CPIUK$ PtUS CPI US t log US P1900 PtUK St CPI UK $ t log UK P S 1900 1900 St is $/£ - exchange rate. CPIs show similar developments: supports long-run relative PPP. Still, CPIUS seems to grow faster than CPIUK$: why? See later slide. Goods arbitrage increased in period, but no clearer co-movement at end than at begin. Evidence of PPP is not conclusive yet. Source: Taylor and Taylor (2004): The Purchasing Power Parity Debate, Journal of Economic Perspectives Explaining deviations from PPP Explaining deviations from PPP Economic reasons 1. Trade costs and impediments goods arbitrage ↓ 2. Tradables vs. non-tradables (see next slides) 3. Productivity differentials: Balassa-Samuelson (see next slides). 22/28 2: Tradables vs. non-tradables Basic mechanism behind PPP: goods arbitrage Unrealistic for nontraded goods (non-tradables): PN ≠ SPN* even if PT = SPT* (N for no-tradables, T for tradables). Consequence for aggregate price levels: P ≠ SP*. Finding P≠SP* may cause false conclusion of incomplete goods arbitrage Also test PT = SPT* (so using just tradables) when testing for PPP. 23/28 Redo 200-years analysis: PPI instead of CPI PPI series show stronger evidence of long-run relative PPP than CPI series before consistent with fact that PPI has fewer nontradables than CPI: PPI is more like PT. Source: Taylor and Taylor (2004): The Purchasing Power Parity Debate, Journal of Economic Perspectives 3: Productivity differentials Take prices of baskets of a limited number of similar goods across countries Scatter plot, where each dot is one country in 2010 US Observation: Prich > SP*poor. China Real per capita income (in 2005 U.S. dollars) 25/28 Source: Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz: International Economics, eleventh edition Balassa-Samuelson explanation of Prich > SP*poor Idea: Take a rich country and compare it to a poor country. Prices of tradables are equal (due to international competition), but productivity for tradables is higher (in rich) Wages in tradables sector are higher Wages in non-tradables sector are higher (as labor mobility within country reduces labor supply in non-tradables) Prices in non-tradables sector are higher (as productivity is equal) Aggregate price level is higher: Prich > SP*poor. 26 Conclusion Evaluation of PPP PPP is based on goods market arbitrage. Empirical validity: In short-run:(relative) PPP is invalid. In long-run: (relative) PPP is valuable. Conclusions: PPP is useful for long-run exchange rate determination PPP is incomplete explanation of exchange rate in short-run add money/capital flows: next chapters. Do we now understand the “What you will learn”-slide? 28