Podcast
Questions and Answers
The Current Population Survey (CPS) collects labor force statistics annually.
The Current Population Survey (CPS) collects labor force statistics annually.
False (B)
An individual working 4 non-paid hours during the reference week is classified as employed according to CPS definitions.
An individual working 4 non-paid hours during the reference week is classified as employed according to CPS definitions.
False (B)
According to the CPS definitions, a person who was temporarily laid off from their job and is waiting to be recalled is considered unemployed.
According to the CPS definitions, a person who was temporarily laid off from their job and is waiting to be recalled is considered unemployed.
True (A)
The labor force (LF) is calculated by subtracting the number of unemployed (U) individuals from the number of employed (E) individuals: $LF = E - U$.
The labor force (LF) is calculated by subtracting the number of unemployed (U) individuals from the number of employed (E) individuals: $LF = E - U$.
Individuals under the age of 16 and those who are institutionalized are included in the Current Population Survey (CPS) when determining labor force statistics.
Individuals under the age of 16 and those who are institutionalized are included in the Current Population Survey (CPS) when determining labor force statistics.
To maintain constant utility while decreasing consumption, an individual should be offered less leisure.
To maintain constant utility while decreasing consumption, an individual should be offered less leisure.
Indifference curves closer to the origin represent higher levels of utility, assuming consumption and leisure are both ‘goods’.
Indifference curves closer to the origin represent higher levels of utility, assuming consumption and leisure are both ‘goods’.
Indifference curves can cross if individuals have complex preferences that change over time.
Indifference curves can cross if individuals have complex preferences that change over time.
Indifference curves are concave to the origin due to the assumption of increasing marginal utility.
Indifference curves are concave to the origin due to the assumption of increasing marginal utility.
Workers with shallower indifference curves value their leisure relatively more than workers with steeper indifference curves.
Workers with shallower indifference curves value their leisure relatively more than workers with steeper indifference curves.
If Cameron dislikes working and enjoys video games, his indifference curves would likely be steeper, indicating a high valuation of leisure (time spent playing video games).
If Cameron dislikes working and enjoys video games, his indifference curves would likely be steeper, indicating a high valuation of leisure (time spent playing video games).
During the 'Great Resignation,' workers who became more dissatisfied with their jobs likely developed shallower indifference curves, reflecting a decreased valuation of leisure relative to consumption.
During the 'Great Resignation,' workers who became more dissatisfied with their jobs likely developed shallower indifference curves, reflecting a decreased valuation of leisure relative to consumption.
If Erin greatly enjoys working and dislikes free time, her indifference curves would likely be flatter, indicating a preference for leisure over consumption.
If Erin greatly enjoys working and dislikes free time, her indifference curves would likely be flatter, indicating a preference for leisure over consumption.
As an individual moves along an indifference curve, the willingness to trade between consumption and leisure remains constant due to a fixed utility level.
As an individual moves along an indifference curve, the willingness to trade between consumption and leisure remains constant due to a fixed utility level.
Marginal utility of a good can be negative, indicating that consuming more of that good decreases overall utility.
Marginal utility of a good can be negative, indicating that consuming more of that good decreases overall utility.
If the partial derivative of a utility function with respect to leisure, $\frac{\partial U(C,L)}{\partial L}$, is equal to zero, it implies that consumption provides no utility.
If the partial derivative of a utility function with respect to leisure, $\frac{\partial U(C,L)}{\partial L}$, is equal to zero, it implies that consumption provides no utility.
A convex indifference curve implies increasing marginal utility, suggesting that each additional unit of a good provides more utility than the previous one.
A convex indifference curve implies increasing marginal utility, suggesting that each additional unit of a good provides more utility than the previous one.
The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) represents the rate at which a person is willing to trade one good for another while experiencing a change in utility.
The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) represents the rate at which a person is willing to trade one good for another while experiencing a change in utility.
If Kurt's utility function is U(C,L) = C * L, his MRS (Marginal Rate of Substitution) of leisure for consumption is constant at 1, regardless of the levels of C and L.
If Kurt's utility function is U(C,L) = C * L, his MRS (Marginal Rate of Substitution) of leisure for consumption is constant at 1, regardless of the levels of C and L.
An indifference curve can represent different levels of utility for the same combination of goods, depending on individual preferences.
An indifference curve can represent different levels of utility for the same combination of goods, depending on individual preferences.
Paula's utility function is given by U(C,L) = 2C^3L + CL^2. The marginal utility of consumption (MUc) is equal to $6C^2 + L^2$.
Paula's utility function is given by U(C,L) = 2C^3L + CL^2. The marginal utility of consumption (MUc) is equal to $6C^2 + L^2$.
The official unemployment rate accurately captures the experiences of discouraged workers who have stopped actively seeking employment after an extended period.
The official unemployment rate accurately captures the experiences of discouraged workers who have stopped actively seeking employment after an extended period.
The labor force participation rate (LFPR) is calculated by dividing the total population by the number of people in the labor force.
The labor force participation rate (LFPR) is calculated by dividing the total population by the number of people in the labor force.
The labor force participation rate only considers the extensive margin of labor supply.
The labor force participation rate only considers the extensive margin of labor supply.
Since the 1900s, the labor force participation rate for men aged 55 and older has consistently declined without any recent rebound.
Since the 1900s, the labor force participation rate for men aged 55 and older has consistently declined without any recent rebound.
Increased Health leads inevitably to less people participating in the labor force.
Increased Health leads inevitably to less people participating in the labor force.
The labor force participation rate for married women has decreased and diverged from that of unmarried women over time.
The labor force participation rate for married women has decreased and diverged from that of unmarried women over time.
Average weekly hours worked have generally increased over time, particularly after World War II.
Average weekly hours worked have generally increased over time, particularly after World War II.
Individuals with higher levels of education tend to have lower labor force participation rates and work fewer annual hours.
Individuals with higher levels of education tend to have lower labor force participation rates and work fewer annual hours.
With a 50% tax rate for all hours worked over 40, the budget constraint will have a kink at 40 hours of work.
With a 50% tax rate for all hours worked over 40, the budget constraint will have a kink at 40 hours of work.
If a person has only labor income, their minimum consumption is equal to zero.
If a person has only labor income, their minimum consumption is equal to zero.
If Jessie's take-home wage is $10 per hour and there are 110 total hours, Jessie's maximum possible consumption is $1000, assuming no non-labor income.
If Jessie's take-home wage is $10 per hour and there are 110 total hours, Jessie's maximum possible consumption is $1000, assuming no non-labor income.
If a person faces a constant wage of $5 per hour, has 168 hours in a week, and receives a non-labor income of $200 per week, their consumption is defined by C = 1040 - 5L, where L represents leisure hours.
If a person faces a constant wage of $5 per hour, has 168 hours in a week, and receives a non-labor income of $200 per week, their consumption is defined by C = 1040 - 5L, where L represents leisure hours.
If a person's consumption is defined by C = 840 – 5L + 200, then hours worked does not affect consumption.
If a person's consumption is defined by C = 840 – 5L + 200, then hours worked does not affect consumption.
If a person has a wage of $5 per hour up to 40 hours and $10 per hour after 40 hours, with 168 total hours and $200 non-labor income, their consumption when leisure is 128 hours is $400.
If a person has a wage of $5 per hour up to 40 hours and $10 per hour after 40 hours, with 168 total hours and $200 non-labor income, their consumption when leisure is 128 hours is $400.
If the take-home wage rate is w
, total weekly hours is T
, leisure hours is L
and non-labor income is V
, then consumption C
can be expressed as: $C = wL + V$
If the take-home wage rate is w
, total weekly hours is T
, leisure hours is L
and non-labor income is V
, then consumption C
can be expressed as: $C = wL + V$
In the budget constraint equation C = w(T-L) + V, 'T' represents the amount of taxes paid on labor income.
In the budget constraint equation C = w(T-L) + V, 'T' represents the amount of taxes paid on labor income.
In the neoclassical static labor supply model, if individuals perceive both consumption (C) and leisure (L) as 'bads,' they would still aim to maximize their consumption of both, subject to the budget constraint.
In the neoclassical static labor supply model, if individuals perceive both consumption (C) and leisure (L) as 'bads,' they would still aim to maximize their consumption of both, subject to the budget constraint.
Non-labor income (V) represents a person's earnings that are directly proportional to the number of hours they work.
Non-labor income (V) represents a person's earnings that are directly proportional to the number of hours they work.
The 'static' nature of the model implies that individuals are assumed to optimize their consumption and leisure choices over their entire lifetime, taking into account assets and savings.
The 'static' nature of the model implies that individuals are assumed to optimize their consumption and leisure choices over their entire lifetime, taking into account assets and savings.
According to the full budget constraint equation $C = w(T-L) + V$, an increase in the wage rate (w) will always lead to an increase in consumption (C), regardless of the individual's choice of leisure (L).
According to the full budget constraint equation $C = w(T-L) + V$, an increase in the wage rate (w) will always lead to an increase in consumption (C), regardless of the individual's choice of leisure (L).
In the context of the full budget constraint, the term 'full income' (w*T + V) represents the total amount an individual could earn if they dedicated all their time to leisure.
In the context of the full budget constraint, the term 'full income' (w*T + V) represents the total amount an individual could earn if they dedicated all their time to leisure.
Based on the money budget constraint $C = w*h + V$, if a person's non-labor income (V) increases while their hours worked (h) and wage (w) remain constant, their expenditures (C) will decrease.
Based on the money budget constraint $C = w*h + V$, if a person's non-labor income (V) increases while their hours worked (h) and wage (w) remain constant, their expenditures (C) will decrease.
If the wage rate increases, the budget line will shift inwards, indicating a decrease in the consumption opportunity set.
If the wage rate increases, the budget line will shift inwards, indicating a decrease in the consumption opportunity set.
When prices are not constant, the budget constraint remains linear, but its slope changes at specific consumption levels.
When prices are not constant, the budget constraint remains linear, but its slope changes at specific consumption levels.
Flashcards
Current Population Survey (CPS)
Current Population Survey (CPS)
A survey in the U.S. that provides monthly labor force statistics.
Employed (E)
Employed (E)
Worked at least 1 hour for pay or 15 hours unpaid in a family business.
Unemployed (U)
Unemployed (U)
Temporarily laid off or actively seeking work in the past 4 weeks.
Population (P)
Population (P)
Signup and view all the flashcards
Labor Force (LF)
Labor Force (LF)
Signup and view all the flashcards
Labor Force Participation Rate (LFPR)
Labor Force Participation Rate (LFPR)
Signup and view all the flashcards
Employment Rate
Employment Rate
Signup and view all the flashcards
Unemployment Rate
Unemployment Rate
Signup and view all the flashcards
Discouraged Workers
Discouraged Workers
Signup and view all the flashcards
Underemployed
Underemployed
Signup and view all the flashcards
Extensive Margin
Extensive Margin
Signup and view all the flashcards
Intensive Margin
Intensive Margin
Signup and view all the flashcards
Education & Work Hours
Education & Work Hours
Signup and view all the flashcards
Constant Utility
Constant Utility
Signup and view all the flashcards
Higher Indifference Curves
Higher Indifference Curves
Signup and view all the flashcards
Non-Satiation Assumption
Non-Satiation Assumption
Signup and view all the flashcards
Non-Intersecting Curves
Non-Intersecting Curves
Signup and view all the flashcards
Convex Indifference Curves
Convex Indifference Curves
Signup and view all the flashcards
Diminishing Marginal Utility
Diminishing Marginal Utility
Signup and view all the flashcards
Steep Indifference Curve
Steep Indifference Curve
Signup and view all the flashcards
Leisure Preference
Leisure Preference
Signup and view all the flashcards
Wage (w)
Wage (w)
Signup and view all the flashcards
Hours (h)
Hours (h)
Signup and view all the flashcards
Non-labor income (V)
Non-labor income (V)
Signup and view all the flashcards
Money budget constraint
Money budget constraint
Signup and view all the flashcards
Time budget constraint
Time budget constraint
Signup and view all the flashcards
Full budget constraint
Full budget constraint
Signup and view all the flashcards
Full income
Full income
Signup and view all the flashcards
Budget line slope
Budget line slope
Signup and view all the flashcards
Work-Life Balance
Work-Life Balance
Signup and view all the flashcards
Marginal Utility
Marginal Utility
Signup and view all the flashcards
Marginal Utility of Goods
Marginal Utility of Goods
Signup and view all the flashcards
Marginal Utility of Leisure
Marginal Utility of Leisure
Signup and view all the flashcards
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS)
Signup and view all the flashcards
MRS Formula
MRS Formula
Signup and view all the flashcards
Budget Constraint
Budget Constraint
Signup and view all the flashcards
Consumption Formula (C)
Consumption Formula (C)
Signup and view all the flashcards
Consumption Formula (C) w/ Leisure
Consumption Formula (C) w/ Leisure
Signup and view all the flashcards
Maximum Consumption
Maximum Consumption
Signup and view all the flashcards
Minimum Consumption
Minimum Consumption
Signup and view all the flashcards
Budget Line Formula
Budget Line Formula
Signup and view all the flashcards
"Kinked" Budget Constraint
"Kinked" Budget Constraint
Signup and view all the flashcards
Wage Subsidy
Wage Subsidy
Signup and view all the flashcards
Study Notes
Data and the Labor Force
- The Current Population Survey (CPS) is one of the oldest, largest, and most well-recognized surveys in the United States.
- CPS serves as the primary source of monthly labor force statistics.
- CPS can be used to locate basic information about the labor market.
- Basic definitions apply to individuals 16 and older who are not institutionalized, referring to activities within a reference week.
- Employed (E) refers to working at least 1 paid hour or 15 non-paid hours.
- Unemployed (U) refers to temporary layoff or actively seeking work in the previous 4 weeks.
- Population (P) refers to all individuals in the relevant age range.
- Labor Force (LF) is defined as the sum of Employed and Unemployed individuals (LF = E + U).
- Out of Labor Force (OLF) includes those not in the labor force, calculated as Population minus Labor Force (P = LF + OLF).
- Labor Force Participation Rate is calculated as LF / P.
- Employment Rate is calculated as E / P.
- Unemployment Rate is calculated as U / LF.
- The official definition of U does not account for "Hidden Unemployed", or "discouraged workers" who are classified as OLF.
- "Under employed" describes part-time workers who desire full-time work or those in lower-skilled jobs.
- Older individuals are healthier and working longer due to reasons like technology, medicine, and the decline of manual labor in many positions.
- Labor Force Participation Rate (LFPR) and annual hours worked tend to increase with higher levels of education.
- LFPR tends to decline more with age compared to annual hours.
- Differences in LFPR by race tend to be more significant compared to differences in annual hours.
- Average weekly hours worked have seen a strong decline over time.
- More women are employed part-time compared to men.
- More men who are high school dropouts are employed compared to women with the same level of education.
Preference and Utility
- The basic model is the "Neoclassical static labor supply model."
- It is assumed that workers maximize a utility function, valuing consumption and leisure.
- Consumption refers to all purchased goods and services.
- Leisure is a catch-all for not working.
- The model is similar where an individual is choosing to consume two goods.
- Only a one-period model is considered (static).
- Basic components include preferences over consumption and leisure represented by a utility function, a budget constraint, and the assumption that individuals choose the bundle that maximizes utility within the budget constraint.
- It is assumed that economists are rational and able to optimize consumption given scarce resources.
- Completeness and rankability refers to that individuals comparing bundles of goods and ranking them can happen.
- It is assumed that for most goods, more is better ("monotonicity"), or non-satiation.
- Transitivity means that consistency is applied on rankings; e.g., if A is preferred to B, and B is preferred to C, then A is preferred to C.
- The more one has of a good, the less willing they are to give up something else to get even more of that good.
- Utility is a function that outputs the value of consuming a particular bundle.
- Utility (U) is generated through consumption goods (C) and leisure (L), expressed as U=f(C,L).
- An indifference curve connects all bundles providing the same level of utility.
- Utility functions imply collections of indifference curves.
- Indifference curves are downward-sloping, reflecting that consumers value both consumption and leisure.
- Indifference curves further from the origin (higher) represent higher levels of utility.
- Indifference curves cannot cross, as it leads to logical inconsistencies as U(X)=U(Y), U(Y)=U(Z), and U(Z)>U(X) simultaneously.
- Indifference curves are convex to the origin, as they are defined with the "diminishing marginal utility assumption.
- Diminishing marginal utility means that each additional unit of consumption provides less additional utility when all else is equal.
- Workers with steeper indifference curves value their leisure relatively more.
- Marginal utility is the additional utility from consuming one additional unit of a good, other goods held constant.
- Calculus can be used to show: Marginal utility of consumer goods: MUc = ∂U(C,L) / ∂C and Marginal utility of leisure: MUL = ∂U(C,L) / ∂L
- Marginal utilities must be positive, meaning consuming more always provides positive utility.
- Dimninishing marginal utility means that indifference curves are convex to the origin
- The indifference curve shows how an individual is willing to trade between the goods.
- Marginal Rate of Substitution = tradeoff between two marginal utilities
Budget Constraint
- The budget constraint is the second component of the neoclassical static labor supply model.
- Individuals maximize consumption of both goods; the budget constraint limits consumption.
- Wage (w) is the hourly wage an individual can earn.
- Hours (h) is the number of hours an individual works.
- Non-labor income (V) is income that doesn't depend on work.
- The model is static; considering a point to be living just one year.
- Therefore, Consumption (C) equals total income.
- The money budget constraint is defined as C = wh + V, where expenditures (C) equal labor income (wh) plus non-labor income (V).
- The time budget constraint is defined as T = h + L, where total hours available (T) are divided between work (h) and leisure (L).
- Combining constraints gives: C = w(T-L) + V = (wT + V) – wL, where (wT + V) is "full income" if all time were spent working.
- Individuals choose to allocate their income between Consumption and Leisure.
- The price of leisure shown is the wage rate.
- The endpoints on a budget line are when L=0, so C=wT + V, or when L=T so C=V.
- One endpoint (E) can be called the endowment point.
- The slope of the budget line is -w, representing the financial trade-off between Leisure and Consumption.
- Non-standard budget constraints include overtime pay, taxes on wages above a certain amount, or subsidies on wages below a certain amount.
Studying That Suits You
Use AI to generate personalized quizzes and flashcards to suit your learning preferences.