Public Economics: Principles and Practice PDF

Document Details

Uploaded by Deleted User

2018

Peter Abelson

Tags

public economics economic principles government policy policy implications

Summary

This textbook, Public Economics: Principles and Practice, by Peter Abelson, explores the role of government in the economy. It examines a range of topics, including market failures, public goods, social welfare, and taxation policies. The book explores how economic principles apply to government action as well as market economics, focusing on microeconomic principles.

Full Transcript

Public Economics: Principles and Practice: On-Line Edition Contents for Print PDF Publication 2018 Preface to Public Economics On-Line Edition 2018 i Preface to Public Economics 3rd Edition 2012...

Public Economics: Principles and Practice: On-Line Edition Contents for Print PDF Publication 2018 Preface to Public Economics On-Line Edition 2018 i Preface to Public Economics 3rd Edition 2012 iii Outline of Public Economics On-Line Edition 2018 vi About the Author xi Part 1 Nature of Government Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 1 Chapter 2 Government in Practice 20 Part 2 Markets and Government Chapter 3 Competitive Markets: Efficiency and Welfare 39 Chapter 4 Market Failures, Equity and Government 56 Chapter 5 Economic Growth and Government 72 Part 3 Economic Evaluation and Public Policy Chapter 6 Valuing Individual Preferences 91 Chapter 7 Social Welfare and Economic Evaluation 113 Chapter 8 Cost–Benefit Analysis 131 Part 4 Public Choice Chapter 9 Public Choice and Individual Values 153 Chapter 10 Public Choice in Practice 167 Part 5 Building Economic Foundations Chapter 11 Public Goods 185 Chapter 12 Education 205 Chapter 13 Externalities and Environment 222 Chapter 14 Competition Policy and Industry Regulation 239 Chapter 15 Information and Safety 256 Part 6 Public Supply of Goods and Services Chapter 16 Delivering Efficient Public Services 275 Chapter 17 Pricing Public Services 293 Chapter 18 Public or Private Production and Ownership 309 Chapter 19 Economic Infrastructure: Transport 323 Part 7 Social Welfare and Income Redistribution Chapter 20 Poverty and Inequality 341 Chapter 21 Social Welfare by Market Regulation 362 Chapter 22 Social Welfare Provision 378 Chapter 23 Welfare Programs for the Workforce, Families and the Elderly 399 Chapter 24 Health 420 Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au Part 8 Public Finance and Taxation Chapter 25 Introduction to Public Finance 437 Chapter 26 Incidence of Taxation 452 Chapter 27 Taxation and Efficiency 471 Chapter 28 Optimal Taxation and Tax Reform 491 Chapter 29 Government Borrowing and Debt 510 Part 9 Taxation in Practice Chapter 30 Taxation of Personal Income 527 Chapter 31 Corporate Taxation 545 Chapter 32 Taxation of Consumption, Wealth and Not-for-Profit Organisations 562 Part 10 Multi-Government Systems Chapter 33 Multilevel Government 581 Chapter 34 Globalisation and Government 602 Epilogue 621 Glossary 623 References 629 Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au Public Economics: Principles and Practice Preface to On-Line Edition It is a pleasure to bring to you an on-line, open-access, edition of Public Economics: Principles and Practice. Public economics is the study of the role of government in the economy. As I remarked in the Preface to the Third Edition in 2012: “It is hard to think of a more important and topical field of study in the social sciences”. This is surely as true in this turbulent world today as it was then. It is a core thesis of the book that government is a fundamental instrument of the social welfare of communities. As described in the book, government has traditionally played a fundamental role in both economic development and social welfare in Australia, as indeed it has in many other countries. In taking this view of government, we are following the European tradition more closely than the American (US) one which tends to elevate markets and distrust government. Of course, the picture is complicated with many variations within these political cultures and with many reasons for and against both governments and markets, which we discuss at many points in the book. On a personal note, I may say that when I completed the Third Edition six years ago in 2012, I had no intention to prepare another Edition. At that time, I had completed 47 years of professional life. This included ten exotic years of economic consulting work in 13 countries around the globe and 37 years of much more sedentary though very pleasant life in Australian Universities in Sydney (Macquarie and Sydney University). I was then (in 2012) about to move out of academic life into local government as Mayor of my local community in Sydney (Mosman) for 5 years as well as part-time economic consultancy work, including for the NSW (state) Government, which was to prove a slightly tricky combination at times. This renewed experience in government was a source of great pleasure and fully confirmed for me the importance of government in community welfare. At the same time, we were observing extraordinary and deeply disturbing economic and political developments around the world: increases in inequality within countries, anger with globalisation of trade and international movements of labour, the vacuous Brexit debates, the extraordinary election of a President of the United States with neither knowledge of nor aptitude for government, and within Australia a distrust of both major parties leading to more minority parties and weak government. A theme common to all these events was deep distrust of government. I was therefore delighted when McGraw-Hill (publisher of the Second and Third Editions) agreed in December 2017 to revert the rights of Public Economics to me, thus allowing me to publish a revised version of the 2012 text in full on line. In the short time available since then, I have edited and partially updated the 2012 edition. This includes a minor restructure with the original Part 9 (Social Welfare and Income Redistribution) advanced to Section 7. However, at this stage I have included few new academic references. And I am aware that many other improvements can be made. i Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au Subject to sufficient interest, I plan is to revise the book regularly and to provide this as an ongoing, open access, publication. I invite, and would be most grateful for, any suggestions for improvements and updating. I hope that this will contribute to an informed and inclusive discussion of these issues that are so important to our individual and collective welfare both here in Australia and in many other countries. In preparing this online edition I have received valuable research assistance from Thomas Bennett. I also wish to acknowledge the great support that my wife, Jeanne, has given me once again while I have been preparing this online addition. Dr. Peter Abelson Sydney, Australia April 2018 ii Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au Public Economics: Principles and Practice Preface to 3rd Edition 2012 Public economics is the study of the role of government in the economy. This study includes nearly all aspects of public expenditure and finance and government economic policies. By convention, it does not include macroeconomic management which is generally treated as a separate subject. Thus, public economics may also be described as the study of the role of government in economic efficiency and distribution. In the language of economics, the study is both positive and normative. The positive part is the study of how government actually affects the economy. The normative part is the study of how government ought to affect the economy. These studies inevitably involve elements of political science and moral philosophy respectively. In the preface to his influential book, The Economics of Welfare, Arthur Pigou observed nearly 100 years ago that: ‘The complicated analyses which economists endeavour to carry through are not mere gymnastic. They are instruments for the betterment of life.’ This view motivates many of us who work in the field of public economics. Our fundamental goal in studying public economics is to understand both how the arrangement of economic affairs in a country, whether by markets or by government, affect the welfare of individuals that make up society and how these arrangements can be improved. This study has been a central part of the study of economics or of political economy at least since the publication of Adam Smith’s famous book, The Wealth of Nations, in 1776. Indeed, it is hard to think of a more important and topical field of study in the social sciences. Content of Public Economics: Principles and Practice In Public Economics I attempt to provide an understanding of the whole field of public economics. This includes the study of the role of markets and of government in the economy, methods of economic evaluation and their applications to public policy, the political economy of government policy making, the principles and practice of public expenditure, policies for social assistance and income redistribution, taxation principles and practice, and multilevel systems of government. As is customary in public economics, the discussion is based on microeconomic principles. The content of public economics is determined more by its subject matter than by the introduction of new economic methods of analysis. A theme of the book is that basic economic principles apply to government as they do to markets although not always in quite the same way. I also try to convey both the rigorous and consistent principles that underlie the economic approach to public economics and how these principles can be applied to practical issues. The principles and the practice are complementary. Without the principles, public policies would be poorly based. Without the practical applications, the principles would be of little interest or use. I hope that this book will help readers understand and appreciate how good economic policies can enhance the welfare of the communities in which we live. In its structure and major content, this third edition is similar to the second. But, in parts, the content has been significantly revised. The world has changed remarkably in the last five years. There is much less iii Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au trust of markets following the global financial crisis and yet globalising market forces are stronger than ever. Also, in recent years, both the amount of economic data available and the volume of empirical studies have increased significantly. I have tried to incorporate an understanding of these contemporary forces and changes, as well as other technical revisions, into this book. Readers of Public Economics: Principles and Practice The book is written as an introduction to public economics. I expect that most readers will have studied economics for one or two years before undertaking a study of public economics or public finance. However, I have tried to produce a book that will also be accessible in the most part to readers with less background in economics, and interesting to those with more knowledge of economics. Readers in one or other of these categories may find selected parts of the book of interest. The book will doubtless be of most interest to Australian readers, or Australian-based students, because I give mainly Australian examples. However, I also provide international comparisons throughout. For teachers of public economics who use this text, PowerPoint slides and answers to the discussion questions are available from the publisher. Acknowledgments In preparing this and the previous two editions, I have received an enormous amount of assistance and accumulated numerous debts. I must especially thank Glenn Withers (Australian National University), Pundarik Mukhopadhaya (Macquarie University) and John Freebairn (Melbourne University). Glenn provided advice and encouragement over much of the development of the first edition. Pundarik co- authored three chapters (Chapters 3, 6 and 28, now 20) in the second edition and commented helpfully on several other chapters. John Freebairn commented in detail on the taxation Chapters 20 to 27 (now 25 to 32) in both the second and third editions. I was also helped greatly at various times by four outstanding research assistants—Vinita Doedhar, Raymond Li, Sandra Redmond and Amanda Sayegh. I should also like to thank the many colleagues around Australia who have generously taken the time to review draft chapters of one or other editions of the book (and in some cases, more than one edition). These reviewers include: Francisco Azpitarte (Melbourne University), Fred Argy (past Director of the then Economic Planning and Advisory Commission), Jeff Bennett (Australian National University), Geoffey Brennan (Australian National University), Michael Brooks (University of Tasmania), Tony Bryant (Macquarie University), Helen Cabalu (Curtin University of Technology), Stephen Cheung (Sydney University), Harry Clarke (La Trobe University), Michael Coelli (Melbourne University), Michael Cosgrave (Australian Competition and Consumer Commission), Michael Dobbie (Macquarie University), Brian Dollery (University of New England), Stephen Dowrick (Australian National University), Joanne Epp (New South Wales Treasury), Hayley Fisher (Sydney University), Peter Forsyth (Monash University), David Gadiel (Director of Applied Economics), Partha Gangopadhya (University of Western Sydney), Noel Gaston (Bond University), Jenny Gordon (Productivity Commission) and anonymous colleagues at the Productivity Commission who reviewed various chapters, Eric Groom (NSW Independent Pricing and Regulatory Tribunal), Ross Guest (Griffith University), Ann Harding (University of Canberra), David Hensher (University of Sydney), Shane Johnson (Australian Treasury), Glenn Jones (ex–Macquarie University), Roselyne Joyeux (Macquarie University), Geoffrey Kingston (University of New South Wales), Andrew Leigh (ex–Australian iv Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au National University), Kwang Ng (Monash University), David Maynard (ex–New South Wales Treasury), Paul Miller (University of Western Australia), Neville Norman (Melbourne University), Rod O’Donnell (University of Technology), Chris Panousis (Griffith University), Johnathan Pincus (Adelaide University), David Prentice (La Trobe University), John Quiggin (University of Queensland), Maria Racionero (Australian National University), Jeff Sheen (Macquarie University), Noree Siddique (Flinders University), David Throsby (Macquarie University), Andrew Torre (Deakin University), Tom Valentine (ex –University of Western Sydney), Michael Warlters (New South Wales Treasury), Stephen Whelan (Sydney University), Peter Whiteford (University of New South Wales), Ross Williams (Melbourne University) and Erkan Yalcin (University of New England). These reviews were a great assistance. Needless to say, none of the reviewers is responsible for any shortcomings in the book. My thanks are also due to the School of Economics, Sydney University, which has provided me with a convivial home for the past six years. I have also been assisted greatly in the preparation of the work at various times by Jane Oldroyd, Helen Boneham, Clara Liosatos and Laura Billington. I wish, especially, to thank Clara for working long hours over the last year in her spare time to make this publication possible and Laura for standing in at the last critical moments. I am also grateful to McGraw-Hill’s proof reader, Anne Savage, and Publisher Kate Aylett–Graham for their excellent and helpful assistance in the final stages of the production. Above all, I thank my family and my wife, Jeanne, for their support and tolerance. They predicted the amount of time required to complete the third (and earlier) editions much more accurately than I did. Peter Abelson University of Sydney May 2012 v Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au About the Author Peter Abelson graduated from Oxford University and gained an M.Sc and Ph.D in Economics from London University. Peter started his career in international economic consulting from 1966 to 1974. In 1974 he joined the Economics Department at Macquarie University in Sydney, where he held a Personal Chair in Economics from 2001 to early 2006. From 1993 to 2006, Peter was Secretary of the Economic Society of Australia. From 2006 to 2012, Peter was a Visiting Scholar and lecturer in public finance at Sydney University, a part-time Principal Economic Advisor to the NSW Treasury and a Director of Applied Economics, an economic consultancy practice. Peter was a councillor on Mosman Council (Sydney) from 1979 to 1989 and was Mayor from 1983 to 1985. In 2012, he returned to Council as the first popularly elected Mayor of Mosman for a period of 5 years. He continued to work part-time as an economic consultant. Peter is married to Jeanne and they have three (adult) children, David, Julian and Antonia. xi Copyright 2018 Peter Abelson, Applied Economics www.appliedeconomics.com.au Pa r t 1 Nature of G o v er n m en t 2 Part 1 Nature of Government C ha p t e r Fou n da t ion s of 1 P ub lic Economics I think of the state as an association of individuals engaged in a cooperative venture, formed to resolve problems of coexistence and to do so in a democratic and fair manner. Richard M usgrave Government and the State ♦ General Functions of Government ♦ Economic Functions of Government ♦ Historical Perspective ♦ Public Policy and Principles of Economic Analysis I n 1998, the Center for Economic Studies at the University of Munich held a week-long workshop to discuss two major contrasting visions of the role of the state presented by two famous economists, Richard Musgrave and James Buchanan. In the words of Hans- Werner Sinn, Musgrave’s book, The Theory of Public Finance written in 1959 was “a landmark in the field for decades… laying the foundations for the way public finan ce economists around the world think about the state”. 1 On the other hand, in 1986 Buchanan received the Nobel Prize in Economics as the principal founder of the School of Public Choice. Their backgrounds and views were quite different. Richard Musgrave spent the first 30 years of his life in Germany, had a strong social democratic background and was schooled in German public finance. As shown by the quotation at the head of this chapter, drawn from this workshop, Musgrave was a strong believer in the role of the state as a provider of community wellbeing , though as a refugee from Nazi Germany he was also deeply aware of how things could go terribly wrong. On the other hand, by his own description, James Buchanan came from a long line of deeply independent Scots -Irish immigrants to Tennessee in the south of the United States, who bitterly recalled the defeat in the Civil War in the 1980s and for whom there could be “no sense of membership in a genuine national community”. He then studied at the University of Chicago where “the Chicago economist learns how economies work rather than how economies might be controlled”. These experiences led Bu chanan, like the Chicago school, to advocate a strongly constrained role of government. These differences lie at the heart of study of public economics. 2 Economic and social well- being require good government. A good government provides the institutions and rules that allow markets to flourish, effort to be rewarded and people to lead prosperous and healthy lives. It supplies essential public services, including law and order, economic infrastructure, 1 T he workshop and papers were published in Buchanan and Musgrave, 1999, Public Finance and Public Choice: Two Contrasting Visions of the State, MIT Press, Cambridge, USA. T he quotations above are from this book. 2 T hey also lie at the heart of the differences between the Obama and T rump administrations in the US. Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 3 and basic health and education services. It seeks to unify the community, assist the poor and protect the vulnerable. To provide these goods, government must have wide-ranging powers. Government must have the power to defend the community from external aggression, to provide internal security, to make and enforce the laws necessary for economic activities and to provide the basic public goods that a society needs. Moreover, it must have the power to fund these collective activities. As John Stuart Mill remarked, there is ‘in almost all forms of government agency, one thing which is compulsory: the provision of the pecuniary means. These are derived from taxation’.3 But governments may misuse their powers. Governments may act arbitrarily and oppressively, levy excessive taxes well over the value of services supplied, engage in corrupt activities, rule over stagnating or declining economies and increase rather than reduce the divisions in society. These are complex matters. What are the objectives of government? How can governments achieve these objectives? What are the appropriate economic functions and policies of government? And what constraints should be put on government? While, as economists, our main contribution is to assess and propose suitable economic policies, in doing so we have to understand the political and social environment in which we are living and working. Accordingly, in this opening chapter we start by discussing the relationships between the government, the state and the individuals who make up the state. We then move on to examine the main functions of government. The last part of the chapter outlines some of the major principles of economics that we will draw on throughout the book to analyse government policies and actions. Box 1.1 Government and state Government and state are often described by reference t o sovereign state. It alone has the authority to make treaties with each other. A government is the governing power of the foreign states and international bodies. Also, it usually ha s t he state. On the other hand, a state cannot exist without a superior authority in internal affairs. government. How then are government and state Because government acts for the state, it has many of the distinguished? state’s characteristics, including its sovereignty powers. The state represents the political organisation of societ y. Government has a monopoly on the legitimate use of force It is the way in which the members of a society associate and through the military forces and the police. It has the power t o organise under a system of government for the purpose of compel all residents of the state (not only citizens) to obey the reaching and implementing collective decisions. The primary rules it makes on behalf of the state. purpose of the state is to maintain order and security, which But there are important differences between the s ta te a nd it does by a system of law backed by force. The principal the government. All citizens are members of a state, not of characteristics of the state are sovereignty and a defined government. States go to war; governments declare and geographical area within which the state is sovereign. In this conduct war. The head of the state may be different fr om t he area, the state has supreme and exclusive authority. The head of the government. The state, not government, owns government is the practical embodiment of this authority. public resources. A state has a high measure of continuity, The word ‘state’ is also used to describe some politically although not necessarily permanence; governments can change organised communities that are not sovereign states. regularly. Opposing the state is widely regarded as treason, but Examples are the states of the United States of America a nd citizens can oppose the government. In democracies, the the Commonwealth of Australia, which are members of a government’s power of sovereignty is subject to t he per iodic federal union. In these countries, the federal union is the consent of the people. 3 Mill (1848), Principles of Political Economy, p. 944, in W.J. Ashley (ed.) (1909). 4 Part 1 Nature of Government Government and the State In political science, government is commonly defined as ‘the governing power of the state’. The government directs the affairs of the state and is the vehicle for collective action. However, in a democratic state, the exercise of this power is subject to the periodic consent of the people in national elections. The relationship between government and state is described more fully in Box 1.1 (above). The nature of government is revealed more pragmatically in the institutions of government. As shown in Figure 1.1, in a democracy government generally consists of three branches: the legislature, executive and judiciary. The legislature makes the laws; the executive develops government policy and carries out the business of government; the judiciary interprets and applies the laws. The legislature often consists of two houses of parliament: one house initiates legislation and the other reviews it.4 The executive branch includes public administration and services, the armed forces and police, statutory authorities and public trading enterprises. The judicial branch generally comprises a hierarchy of courts. Government services can also be divided into budget and non-budget sectors, based on the sources of finance. The budget sector consists of all activities that are financed out of the annual government budget. This includes most government services, the military, the police, and the courts. It also includes not-for-profit statutory authorities such as universities and public broadcasting authorities which are financed partly through the budget. These authorities are usually established by legislation and have separate legal identity and s ome autonomy, sometimes including revenue raising powers. However, their autonomy is constrained by their statutory responsibilities, their reliance on government funding and government’s power (subject to the governing legislation) to appoint and dismiss directors. The Constitution Rules of the State Bill of Rights International laws Head of State Legislature Executive Judiciary Prime M inister/ Houses of Parliament Higher courts Cabinet Public Government Public trading Lower M ilitary Police administration services enterprises courts Figure 1.1 Typical institutions of government in a democracy 4 T here are exceptions, such as New Zealand, where the legislature consists of only one house. Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 5 The non-budget sector consists of public trading enterprises (PTEs) that finance all or most of their activities by trade revenues. PTEs are usually wholly owned by the state, but in some cases the state owns a majority share. The revenues generated by PTEs give them some autonomy. However, government generally controls the board of directors , regulates major investment and pricing decisions and may provide financial support through the budget. So, what is government? In popular discussion the term ‘government’ usually refers to the agencies of government that ‘govern the state’ the agencies which make rules and policies and provide the main civilian administrative services. Publicly employed teachers and broadcasters may not think of themselves as part of the government. However, when discussing economic issues, such as government expenditure, the term ‘government’ generally applies to all budget-sector services, including the armed forces, budget-financed statutory authorities and the courts. More broadly still, the public sector includes PTEs as well as budget-sector services. In this book we discuss both the role of government and the broader economic issues of the whole public sector. Constraints on government In nearly all states, government is based on a written constitution.5 The constitution represents a superior law that defines the basic institutions and rules of the state, and the methods of appointment and powers of the head of state and the government. The constitution is a critical legal constraint on government actions. Constitutions are generally hard to change, with change requiring a high degree of public assent. In Australia, a change to the constitution requires the support of the majority of all voters and the support of the majority of voters in at least four of the six states. Along with a constitution, most countries also have a bill of rights that provides individuals with legal protection against oppressive government action. Australia is one of the few countries that does not have such protection of individual liberties. A related constraint on the power of government is the separation of powers between its three main branches. This separation has long been viewed as essential for the avoidance of tyranny by government.6 The independence of the judiciary is especially important. This independence enables it to strike down laws that are contrary to the constitution and to punish members of the executive for actions contrary to law, including illegal use of power against citizens. The separation of powers has been adopted most fully in presidential forms of government, as in the United States and France. In these countries, the legislature and the head of the executive branch (the President) are elected in separate elections. Members of the legislature are not normally members of the executive. By contrast, in a parliamentary system, as in the UK and Australia, members of the executive are generally members of the legislature. The governing party controls both the legislature and the executive arm of government. However, this control is rarely absolute. When the legislature consists of two chambers, the second chamber usually has some legislative power and the executive branch of government may not control both chambers. Also, the executive branch usually has many departments. Both ministers of departments and officers within departments often fight fiercely over policy control and administrative territory. A federal form of government is a further important constraint on the power of central government. In a federation, such as the United States and Australia, power is shared between the central government and the states that make up the federation, with the powers of the states supported by the constitutions of the respective countries. The federal structure of government dilutes the power of the centre, encourages competition between government authorities and sets up more checks and balances within the overall government structure. In a 5 All countries, except Israel, New Zealand and the United Kingdom, have a written constitution. 6 See Montesquieu, De L’esprit des Lois (1748, The Spirit of the Laws). 6 Part 1 Nature of Government unitary state, like France and the UK, the central legislature has supreme authority to make laws for the whole country.7 Finally, national governments are constrained by international laws and agreements. Whether for reasons of good international governance or self-interest, governments have been increasingly signing international agreements, including agreements on economic issues such as trade, the environment including climate change, and labour conditions. For example, Australia’s trading laws are derived almost entirely from treaties entered into through the (then) General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (now World Trade Organization) and at the time of writing it appears that Australia will join the Trans Pacific Partnership trade agreement. On the other hand, Brexit and Trump’s America First policies are currently undoing many long-standing international agreements. General Functions of Government Views on the general functions of government depend critically on (1) how people regard the relationship between the individual and the state and (2) how people view the relative effectiveness of markets and government. We discuss these two issues in turn. Historically there have been two main views of the state: the organic and the mechanistic. In the organic view, society is a natural organism like a human body. Each individual is a part of this organism, but the body has an existence in its own right. The organic model implies that the state has an underlying being and value. Thus, Aristotle (c. 340 BC) wrote Organic state that ‘the city or state has priority over the household and over any individual among us. For The state has value the whole must be prior to the parts … It is clear that the state is both natural and prior to the in itself individual’.8 It follows that government should act in the interest of the state as well as for individuals. However, in the 20th century these views were associated with the fascist regimes in Germany and Italy and the totalitarian regimes of Stalinist Russia and Maoist China and became discredited. In these countries, government viewed itself as synonymous with the state. Opposition to government was viewed as opposition to the state. There were few constraints on government power and individual interests were sacrificed to the supposed interests of the state. The mechanistic model of the state is more democratic. In this model, individuals form a Mechanistic state nation for the purpose of making collective decisions. The state is a mechanism for improving The state is a means individual welfare. Government is an instrument of the people who make up the state and a for improving the means of enabling collective actions. The government is subject to law. Government actions welfare of the citizens and social outcomes are judged by their effects on the welfare of individual members of society. In the words of Mill (1859), ‘the worth of the State, in the long run, is the worth of the individuals comprising it’. As described in Box 1.2, leading political writers have advocated a mechanistic model of the state for over 300 years. Today, it is the dominant model. Most countries have a constitution that embodies two key principles the sovereignty of the people and respect for human rights. The state is designed to serve the people, not the converse. This model of the state is also the basis for most economic analysis. Government actions are judged by whether they enhance the welfare of individuals. This is the approach adopted in this book. However, the organic view of the state is not solely of historic significance. Some Islamic states may be regarded as versions of an organic society. Even in secular states, many citizens view society as more than the individuals that comprise it and consider a strictly individualistic approach to collective issues an unattractive and inappropriate view of society. 7 T he UK government has recently devolved significant executive powers to local parliaments for Scotland and Wales, but it has retained major taxation and monetary controls. 8 Aristotle, The Politics, Penguin Classics (1962), p. 29. Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 7 Box 1.2 Origins of the mechanistic state Thomas Hobbes (1651) was one of the first writers to power to protect these natural rights, but its powers are articulate a mechanistic model of the state in his famous book limited broadly to these responsibilities. Leviathan. Writing in turbulent times in England, Hobbes If the government fails to protect man’s natural right s or argued that, because men are largely selfish and competitive, oversteps its responsibilities, the citizens are entitled to the natural condition of mankind is ‘war of every man agains t establish a different government. While Locke was wr it ing, every man’ in which there is ‘continual fear , and danger of the British parliament established by legislation that the violent death; and the life of man, solitary, poor, nasty, executive (King William II) could not tax without its consent. brutish, and short’.9 A state ruled by a sovereign (man or Thus was born the fundamental democratic principle that no assembly) with absolute authority is the only way to avoid man can be taxed without his consent or that of his anarchy. In accepting the benefits of the state, citizens wer e representative. deemed to give up their natural rights and to be under an Nearly 100 years later, the authors of the American obligation of obedience to the sovereign. However, men g iv e Declaration of Independence (1776) declared in ringing tones up their natural rights only for an implicit ‘covenant’ with the that all men are endowed with: sovereign for protection. If the sovereign fails to provide cer tain inalienable r ights, that amongst these ar e life, liber t y protection, men are not obliged to continue to obey the and the pur suit of happiness; that to secur e these r ights, sovereign. gover nments ar e instituted among men, derivin g their jus t powers from the con s en t of the govern ed; that w henever a n y John Locke (1690), in The Second Treatise of Government, for m of gover nment becomes destr uctive of these ends, it is produced a more attractive model of the state. Locke held the r ight of the people to alter or abolish it …’ (author ’s that man has three main natural rights: to life, liberty and italics). property. Men establish a state whose function is to protect Shortly afterwards, the French Declaration of t he Rig ht s these rights. He argued, moreover, that the state rests on an of Man and of the Citizen (1789) declared likewise that the implied socia l contract. The government is entrusted with purpose of political association is to preserve the natural rights of man.10 Alternative views of the role of government Within the dominant mechanistic model of the state, there is a wide range of views about the appropriate role of government. These views depend on judgements about the effectiveness of markets and government and on beliefs about individual freedom and social justice. At one end of the political spectrum, libertarians strongly support private property and advocate very limited government control over markets. For example, Nozick (1974) defends private property on moral grounds : he argues that people have natural rights, liberty is the ultimate political good and state intervention is morally wrong except in limited circumstances to protect natural rights. On the other hand, empirical libertarians, such as Hayek and Milton Friedman, argue that most markets are efficient and that government intervention usually reduces total welfare. They criticise provision of support above subsistence because the resulting institutions, notably taxation, achieve little justice and reduce economic efficiency. In Free to Choose, Milton and Rose Friedman (1980, p.158) conclude that welfare programs “weaken the family; reduce the incentive to work, save and innovate; reduce the accumulation of capital; and limit our freedom”. At the other end of the spectrum, socialists advocate a command and control economy. Socialists see the distribution of rewards in market systems as h ighly unequal and unjust. They view private markets as instruments of exploitation rather than as voluntary exchanges. Owners of capital exploit labour and use resources to meet the demands of the rich. In their 9 Hobbes (1651), Leviathan, pp. 88–89, R. T uck (ed.) (1991) 10 Rousseau’s The Social Contract (1762) was a major influence on the Declaration. But Rousseau viewed man’s rights as social, not natural. He argued that sovereignty resides in the people and that laws should reflect the general will of the people. 8 Part 1 Nature of Government view, government generally allocates resources to meet social needs more efficiently and fairly than do markets. Socialists generally support strong executive government, with fewer constraints imposed by the separation of powers within government. Between these extremes, there are many views about the role of government that cannot be readily classified. Simplifying considerably, we distinguish two further groups: conservatives and social democrats. Conservatives, like libertarians, regard markets as generally efficient. They question active government macroeconomic policies and provision of goods. They generally favour constraints on an activist government and the separation of powers. Because of the element of compulsion in government action, conservatives usually place the burden of proof is on government intervention rather than on markets. However, they are more inclined than libertarians to acknowledge that government can do some things more effectively than the private sector. They also consider that the state has an obligation to support the p oorer groups in society and that it is in the state’s interest to do so to avoid civil disorder. Social democrats recognise that markets are often productive but place more emphasis on the failure of markets to allocate resources efficiently and the unequal outcomes. They view public ownership and private property as pragmatic issues. Government should adopt the ownership mix that best meets society’s goals. Private property is viewed as a means towards achieving social goals rather than as an end in itself. The social democratic tradition emphasises equity. Redistribution is viewed as an appropriate and desirable function of the state. For example, in A Theory of Justice John Rawls (1971) argues that government has a responsibility not just to relieve poverty, but also to achieve a ‘just’ distribution of income. Many Nobel prize winners in economics, such as James Meade, James Tobin and Amartya Sen, hold a similar view. Table 1.1 summarises the views of each of these groups. Much of the debate in public economics about the role of government revolves around these views of the efficiency and fairness of markets and government. Table 1.1 Summary of views of the role of government Political classification Freedom Markets Equity Role of government Libertarians Government a major Markets are very Government often fails to Very limited threat to freedom efficient improve equity Conservatives Government may Markets are Government should Moderate infringe freedom generally efficient alleviate poverty Social democrats Government can Markets are often Government should ensure Considerable enhance freedom inefficient minimum income for all of less well off and reduce inequality Socialists Government frees people Markets are very Government should Very high from want inefficient provide full equity Economic Functions of Government To discuss the economic functions of government it is useful to start with a simple model of the economy. As shown in Figure 1.2, resources are transformed into goods and service s via two major interacting sets of markets, namely factor and product markets. Product markets drive the demand for factors of production (land, labour and capital). On the other hand, incomes generated in factor markets drive the demand for products. In first year texts, this is described as the circular flow of income. Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 9 Resources Processes Outputs Outcomes Inputs Means Goods and Services Welfare Political Market goods institutions Product markets Individual welfare Factor Publicly provided goods Labour, Capital Public supply of Distribution of income markets Environmental goods Natural resources goods Individual liberties Household goods Technology International International trade trade Figure 1.2 The economic process Goods may also be produced in the public or household sectors. Moreover, factors of production and goods may be imported or exported. However, what matters ultimately is individual welfare. This depends not only on the quantity of goods produced, but also on income distribution, non-market goods and political freedoms. Government can intervene in the economic process in various ways. It can regulate any factor or product market, regulate international trade and produce goods in lieu of, or in addition to, market output. It can redistribute ownership of resources and it can redistribute incomes earned in factor markets. Establishing institutions and ground rules. The starting point for any discussion of these roles is that government must establish the institutions and rules that allow markets to work. Markets require an established foundation of law and an effective system of property rights. Property rights include the right to use an asset, to allow or exclude its use by others, to collect the income generated by the asset, and to sell or otherwise dispose of the asset. In the words of the World Bank (1996, pp. 48–49): Property rights are at the heart of the incentive structure of market economies. They determine who bears risk and who gains or loses from transactions. In so doing they spur worthwhile investment, encourage careful monitoring and supervision, and create a constituency for enforceable contacts. In short, fully specified property rights reward effort and good judgement, thereby assisting economic growth and wealth creation. Laws are required to define and protect property rights; to set rules for exchanging these rights; and to enforce contracts. They are also required to establish market structures and to establish rules for entry into and exit out of markets. Enforcement of these laws requires a fair and predictable judicial process. In their eloquent book, Why Nations Fail, Acemoglu and Robinson (2013, p. 43) show that “economic institutions are critical to determining whether a country is poor or prosperous”. They also show that, critically, the political institutions should be inclusive to reward the many and not extractive to reward the few. International experience in the 1990s showed the importance of the rule of law for market operations. In what was known as the “Washington Consensus”, international agencies such as the International Monetary Fund routinely prescribed structural reform and competitive markets to cure underdevelopment, especially in Latin America and the then command and control economies in Eastern Europe. They encouraged privatisation (selling state-owned businesses) and liberalisation. However, these policies failed because the basic institutions and laws were inadequate, the political institutions were extractive and public corruption was common in many of these countries. By the late-1990s, the policy emphasis was on first getting appropriate institutions and laws in place (Rodrik, 2015, pp. 159-167). 10 Part 1 Nature of Government More dramatically and recently, a major cause of the meltdown in financial markets between 2007 and 2009 was the failure of governments to effectively regulate major financial institutions. Manifestly the private institutions failed to self-regulate and the rescue of the financial system cost taxpayers many billions of dollars and, as we will see in Chapters 2 and 29, put many governments heavily into deficit and debt. Given that markets are operating under a functioning political and legal system, what economic services should government provide? The common approach in economic analysis is to assess which goods are supplied inefficiently by markets and might therefore be provided by government. This may appear a biased approach. Why not ask which services government can supply efficiently and leave the rest to markets? There are two main answers. First, if individuals can achieve their goals through voluntary trades in decentralised markets, government direction of individuals or firms is unnecessary. In voluntary trades, all parties expect to benefit. Collective action that simply replicates the actions of free individuals serves no purpose. When compulsion exists, it is always possible that someone is coerced into an exchange against their will. Thus, the general function of government is to accomplish things by collective action that individuals find difficult or impossible to accomplish separately. Second, competitive markets are very good at producing the g oods that people want. Markets coordinate decentralised decisions by generating price signals that reflect demands and relative scarcities without the need for a central planner estimating all these prices. As Adam Smith observed: ‘It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.’ 11 Moreover, it does not matter that each individual: neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it … He intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention … Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it (author’s italics). 12 Smith’s famous metaphor of the invisible hand guiding the competitive economy has now been formalised by economists into the First Theorem of Welfare Economics (see Chapter 3). This theorem states that economies with perfectly competitive markets produce the highest possible level of output and welfare, given the resources and technology available. Although few markets are perfectly competitive, markets generally do quite a good job at producing the goods that people want. Three weaknesses of markets. Despite the invisible hand, markets have three main sets of weaknesses: (1) Market failures: under certain conditions markets allocate re sources inefficiently and fail to supply goods that consumers want; (2) Income inequality: markets often result in inequitable distribution of income; (3) Macroeconomic instability: markets may not produce full employment and price stability. There are four main forms of market failure: public goods, externalities, imperfect Market failures competition and information failures. Markets undersupply public goods, such as national Situations in which security, health and education, which have widespread community benefits. Typically , firms markets allocate cannot charge for all the benefits that accrue from providing these goods. On the other hand, resources inefficiently markets oversupply goods that have damaging (externality) effects on firms or individuals that are not involved directly in the exchange, as occurs with environmenta l damages. Without regulation, markets produce excessive levels of pollution. Third, many markets are not competitive. As Adam Smith famously observed: ‘People of the same trade seldom meet 11 Smith (1776), The Wealth of Nations, p. 14, in E. Cannan (ed.) (1937). 12 Smith (ibid., p. 423). Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 11 together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices’. 13 When markets are not competitive, firms tend to charge excessive prices, restrict output and use excessive resources. Fourth, efficient trading requires that the trading parties are well informed. When poorly informed, one or other party may be made worse off by the trade. Turning to income distribution, in competitive markets workers receive approximately the value of their marginal product. However, because of differences in abilities or opportunities, or simply from accident of birth, the value of the marginal products and therefore the income of individuals vary greatly. All markets, competitive or otherwise, tend to produce an unequal distribution of income. Indeed, there is no guarantee that markets will provide everyone with an adequate living to avoid destitution. Macroeconomic instability typically manifests in price or employment instability. As the Great Depression of the 1930s and the recent global financial crisis showed, markets do not automatically self-correct. Depressed private investment and consumption, along with fear of lending, may create inadequate demand and underemployment. John Maynard Keynes (1936) pointed out that, even if wages were to fall in flexible labour markets, lower wages will not produce full employment in the short run if the aggregate demand for goods is deficient. Less dramatically , markets may produce inefficient fluctuations in economic activity over business cycles. Three potential government functions. These three forms of market weakness provide three potential economic functions for government allocation, redistribution and stabilisation functions.14 The allocation function requires government to respond to market inefficiencies: to provide public goods, regulate externalities, promote competitive markets or regulate market power and protect individuals from information failures. The redistribution function requires government to alleviate poverty and reduce income inequality. The s tabilisation function involves management of aggregate demand to achieve price stability and high levels of employment and to reduce fluctuations in output over the business cycle. 15 However, the extent to which government should carry out any economic role depends not only on the weaknesses of markets but also on the ability of government to deliver improved outcomes. Government actions may be costly or unfair. Government has limited information, is not always efficient and has limited control over private responses to its actions. The key issue is therefore whether government intervention, on balance, increases social welfare. Determining whether government actions increase social welfare is complicated because government actions often have conflicting outcomes. Efficient use of resources may increase income inequality. On the other hand, government actions to redistribute income may reduce the total income available. Attempting to resolve the trade-off between these outcomes is a major issue in public economics. Moreover, governments themselves may not act efficiently. Historical Perspective Economists’ views of the economic functions of government, like popular views, have changed greatly over the last two centuries. For much of the 19th century, most economists advocated a limited role for government. Then, for some 100 years from about 1870 to 1975, economists advocated that government should exercise an increasing role in economic management. In the last quarter of the 20th century, as command and cont rol economies collapsed, many economists viewed markets as more effective than government and sought to 13 Smith (ibid., p. 128). 14 Following Musgrave (1959), government is often described as having three economic branches: an allocation, distribution and stabilisation branch. 15 As noted in the Preface, the stabilisation role is the subject of macroeconomic texts and is not discussed in detail in this book. 12 Part 1 Nature of Government limit the role of government. In the first decade of the new millennium, the global financial crisis along with growing global environmental concerns led to another reversal, with government widely viewed as an essential instrument of global welfare. However, in the last few years popular distrust of governments has again grown, and this has doubtless influenced the thinking of economists.16 Mill, perhaps the most influential economist in the 19th century, held that: Restricting to the narrowest compass the intervention of a public authority in the business of the community... laisser-faire, in short, should be the general practice: every departure from it, unless required by some great good is a certain evil.17... The great majority of things are worse done by the intervention of government, than the individuals most interested in the matter would do them, or cause them to be done, if left to themselves because government has one great disadvantage: an inferior interest in the result.18 Notwithstanding his advocacy for limited government, Mill agreed with all Adam Smith’s proposed government functions (Box 1.3). He regarded the provision of security, the g eneral rule of law and the specific laws of property and contracts as vital for capital accumulation and economic growth.19 He supported government provision of a wide range of public goods, either because of the general expediency and efficiency of collect ive action or because private providers could not be remunerated by user fees. These goods included the coining of money, Box 1.3 Adam Smith’s views on the functions of government Adam Smith’s famous book, The Wealth of Nations, published institutional structure for markets and to remove any in 1776, was an intense reaction against the policies of the restrictions on competition and trade. ‘mercantilists’ who then dominated economic thinking. Smith held that government has three other main duties. Mercantilists argued that the government should control trade. First, to protect society from external threats and violence. They called on government to promote industry and exports Second, to administer justice and to protect every member of and to protect the economy from imported goods. Smith society from internal injustice or oppression, including strongly opposed these protectionist policies, fois t ed upon a commercial injustices. Third, to erect and maintain ‘certain ‘venal parliament by rapacious merchants and manufacturers’, public works and certain public institutions, which it can never along with the complex apparatus of controls that these be for the interest of any individual, or small number of commercial interest groups imposed on other individuals, individuals, to erect and maintain; because the profit could including widespread limitations on apprenticeships, which never repay the expense of any individual, or small number of were a direct restraint on trade. Smith believed that individuals, though it may frequently do much more than repa y competitive markets would produce most of the goods that it to a great society’.21 Although Smith thought that tra nsport people want along with the invention and capital accumulation infrastructure (such as roads, bridges, canals and harbours) to create a steady increase in wealth. However, he held no could fairly be paid for by users, he opposed private pr ovision illusions about the actual nature of markets. ‘Whoever because monopolists with private turnpikes would abuse the imagines that masters rarely combine is as ignorant of the system. He also supported substantial public expenditure on world as of the subject. Masters are always and everywhere in education for youth and for persons ‘of all ages’. 22 This was a sort of tacit, but constant and uniform combination, not t o necessary for a stable and strong country, the unders tanding raise the wages of labour above their actual rate.’ 20 and acceptance of law and the wellbeing of society as a whole. I t was t he government’s job to provide a n a ppropriate 16 T hese are of course generalisations. Many exceptions can be found. 17 Mill (1848), p. 950 in the 1909 edition. 18 Mill (ibid., p. 947). 19 Mill (ibid., p. 881). There needs to be certainty that ‘those who produce shall consume and that those who spare to-day will enjoy to-morrow’. 20 Smith (ibid., pp. 66–67). 21 Smith (ibid., p. 651). 22 Smith (ibid., pp. 739–740). Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 13 prescribing standard weights and measures, surveying and mapping, raising dykes to reduce flooding, irrigation works, street paving and lighting, roads, canals and harbours, hospitals and support for scientific exploration and research academies. Nor did the role of government stop there. Mill acknowledged that the principle of consumer sovereignty could not apply without many exceptions.23 Government should look after those who cannot protect themselves or who fail to choose wisely in life. Moreover, Mill strongly supported public provision of public education. He argued that all society suffers from the consequences of the ignorance and want of education in their fellow citizens. Marx (1867) held a more complex view of government. He held that governments were partly responsible for exploitation of the working classes. However, by taking industry into public ownership, government could radically change property relationships. This would stop exploitation of labour. It would also avoid the collapse of the economy as the return on capital would fall with the growth of capital, thus causing private investment to fall and unemployment to rise. State ownership and control of resources and the means of production were necessary to maintain capital investment and ensure full employment of labour. Increasing the role of government. During the first three-quarters of the 20th century there was increasing public and intellectual support for larger government. The widening of the popular vote to full adult suffrage in many countries increased the legitimacy of government. It also increased the groups in society who could make claims directly on government. Wars had significant impacts. In both the First and Second World Wars many governments, generally with public support and some success, controlled a high proportion of their country’s economic resources including labour and allocated it in accordance with national priorities, introduced extensive price controls and rationing, and expanded the tax base. In 1920, the first major work devoted to welfare economics, Arthur Pigou’s Economics of Welfare, was published. Pigou was concerned not only with poverty and inequality but also with market misallocations of resources. He identified as major problems negative externalities such as industrial pollution, and the misuse of natural resources such as fisheries, forests and farming land. He also argued that people consume too much in the present and save too little. He advocated that government should tax negative externalities, protect the environment and support long-term public projects such as water supply and afforestation. In the 1930s, the Great Depression had a major impact on views of market economies. In the United States, the world’s largest capitalist economy, unemployment reached 25 per cent and national output fell by 30 per cent from its peak in 1929. These falls in employment and output were widely attributed to capitalist speculation and banking failures (Galbraith, 1955). On the other hand, the recovery in the late 1930s was attributed to government expenditures in both democratic states like the United States and fascist states like Germany. President Franklin D. Roosevelt introduced a raft of public works and social welfare programs, known as the ‘New Deal’, to alleviate poverty, unemployment, sickness and old age. Keynes (1936) provided the intellectual support for increased public expenditure. With the collapse of private consumption and failure of private investment to respond lower interest rates, only increased public expenditure would lift aggregate demand sufficiently to drive the economy back to full employment. The Depression scarred public attitudes towards capitalism. In 1943, Joseph Schumpeter wrote: The public mind has by now so thoroughly grown out of humour with it as to make condemnation of capitalism and all its works a foregone conclusion—almost a requirement of the etiquette of discussion. Whatever his political preference, every writer or speaker hastens to conform to this code and to emphasise his critical attitude, his freedom from ‘complacency’, his belief in the 23 Mill (ibid., p. 575) ‘The proposition that the consumer is a competent judge of the commodity can be admitted with only numerous abatements and exceptions.’ 14 Part 1 Nature of Government inadequacies of capitalist achievement, his aversion to capitalism and his sympathy for anti- capitalist interests. 24 After the Second World War, several developments increased the economic role of government. First, many states increased their control over production. China and most Eastern European countries followed the then Soviet Union and became command and control economies. Also, governments in many mixed economies took over ownership of major industries such as coal, steel, railways and power generation. Control of these basic industries was thought necessary to secure capital investment, full employment and growth, to protect workers and to control the prices of necessities. Second, many mixed economies developed strong welfare cultures and services. The Beveridge Report (1942), named after its author, which argued that governments should establish a comprehensive social security fund to provide “from cradle to grave” for the poor, unemployed, sick and elderly, was highly influential in the UK where it was produced and elsewhere. For the next 30 years, many governments expanded the suite of welfare services along with income support and public health and education services. Also, the 1950s and 1960s were a period of decolonisation and independence for many developing countries. Many newly independent governments saw their role in development as pre-eminent. The state would mobilise and direct resources and eliminate social injustices. Markets were part of the discredited colonial system that enriched the coloniser and impoverished the colonised. Prebisch (1970), Head of the Economic Commission for Latin America, articulated a popular school of thought that development would be built on government-owned and supported industries, constructed around high import tariffs and quotas. Also, many countries followed the Indian model, with its centrally planned development within a democratic framework. Reducing the role of government. By the late 1970s, as government spending in many countries exceeded 40 per cent of gross domestic product (GDP), and income transfers accounted a high proportion of tax revenues, attitudes towards government spending a n d t axes started to change. Increased public expenditure appeared to reduce rather than increase rat es o f economic growth. And the command and control economies of the Soviet Union, Eastern Europe and elsewhere were generally performing poorly. US Presidents Ronald Reagan and George H.W. Bush (1981–92) and the UK Conservative governments (1979–97) were strongly committed to smaller government and lower taxes. In his inaugural Presidential address in 1981, Reagan proclaimed that ‘government is not the solution to our problem; government is the problem’. In Australia, Labour governments from 1983 to 1996 and Liberal Coalition governments from 1996 to 2007 favoured, in varying degrees, reforms to encourage competitive markets and restrain the growth of public expenditure (see Chapter 2). Following the lengthy economic boom of the 1990s into the early 2000s, markets were widely perceived to be innovative and productive. While basic public institutions and laws were required, Government was widely perceived to be a constraint on economic growth. The development of public choice theory tended to support these critical views of government. Public choice theory views government not as an abstract benevolent entity that automatically pursues the public interest but as an agency run by individuals who pursue their own interests subject to constraints of elections and various governmental processes. Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem (Arrow, 1951) showed that all methods of making collective decisions, typically by voting, fail quite mild tests for satisfactory process or outcome. Downs (1957) described how elected representatives may pursue their own objectives and make public decisions contrary to the interests of the governed. Niskanen (1971) showed how the private interests of public servants may expand and bias public output. In the last 50 years 24 Schumpeter (1943, p. 63). Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 15 public choice theory has been greatly extended and used increasingly to interpret government behaviour (see Chapters 9 and 10). The new millennium has witnessed extraordinary changes, major uncertainty, the splintering of countries and parties, and no clear overall direction for the role of government. Following many years of economic growth and confidence in markets, in 2007 a tsunami hit the global financial system in 2007. Within 12 months, asset values on the world's largest stock markets halved, giving the lie to the claim that equity markets followed efficient pricing principles. Several of the world's largest financial institutions (Lehman Brothers, Merrill Lynch, Bear Stearns, AIG Insurance, Freddie Mac and Fannie May housing mortgage businesses, the Royal Bank of Scotland) and businesses (General Motors and Chrysler) went bankrupt and were so large as to threaten international financial stability. M any more large companies (including Goldman Sachs) would likely have been bankrupted without massive fiscal and monetary interventions from many of the world ’s largest governments. There were major management failures as markets gave managers incentives to take financial risks where they gained the rewards of success, but others would bear the costs of failure. As revealed by the (US) Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (2011), Wall Street bankers engaged in numerous irresponsible, self-serving, deceitful and unethical practices. These practices were implicitly endorsed by the major credit rating agencies (Moody ’s, Standard and Poor’s and others) who failed to manage their conflicts of interest (being paid by the same large companies that they were rating) and systemically tolerated by the government regulators. Manifestly, under-regulated markets failed. As Reinhart and Rogoff (2010a) showed, financial crises are not one-off exceptions; rather they are endemic features of capitalist economies. Concurrently global concerns about climate change were influencing views of markets and government. The private interests of carbon-producing energy suppliers and consumers were clearly inconsistent with the collective interest in a stable environment. But governments everywhere were finding it difficult to articulate and implement practical climate change policies either domestically or internationally. On the other hand, there has been increasing inequality in many countries (Atkinson, 2015). This has led to growing opposition to globalisation and notably to free trade, free movement of labour and to working under international rules. There is pressure on governments to restrict markets and to minimise free movement of labour across national borders. Thus , the British people voted (narrowly) to leave the European Union (Brexit – British Exit) and the Americans elected a President on an America First ticket who also believed in minimal government while at the same time promising to help the left-behind groups in the US. Thus, after nearly two decades of the new millennium, economists and political scientists are still trying to work out an optimal role for government in an uncertain and unequal world. Public Policy and Principles of Economic Analysis Finally, in this introduction to public economics we consider how economic analysis can contribute to public policy making. The issues are complex and diverse. They may involve, among other things, how much to spend on hospitals and roads, whether and how to regulate markets, what assistance to provide to different groups in society or how to raise revenue. But, whatever the issue, four main questions must nearly always be answered. 1. What are the policy objectives? 2. What are the options for achieving these objectives? 3. What are the implications of each option? 4. Which is the preferred option? 16 Part 1 Nature of Government There is an important difference between these questions or at least between the types of answers that may be given. Understanding this difference is a crucial theme of public economics. Questions 1 and 4 involve value judgements. The answers require judgements about what is desirable: judgements that society would be better off with one objective or outcome than with another. Judgements of desirability, of good and bad, are ethical or moral jud gements. Normative Such judgements are not true or false they are matters of personal values or views. economics Economic analysis that requires ethical judgements is known as normative economics. On Economic analysis the other hand, questions 2 and 3 deal with facts, with how an economy works. Question 2 that involves a deals with how objectives can be achieved. Question 3 deals with the consequences of value judgement government policies. These are empirical questions and the answers are true or false , or accurate or inaccurate (although establishing accuracy may not be easy). Economic analysis that deals with facts is described as positive economics. Positive The branch of economics known as welfare economics provides a powerful framework for economics identifying social objectives and a consistent method for evaluating social choices (see Economic analysis Chapters 7 and 8). However, economists have no special expertise or authority to make of how an economy ethical judgements and we must distinguish carefully between matters that require such actually functions judgements and matters of evidence or fact. Nevertheless, economic analysis is nearly always required to identify the means available to achieve desired social objectives and the implications of these measures. Economic analysis is needed even when government plans to redistribute income, for example to the unemployed or the elderly. In such cases, estimates of the costs and consequences of the options are generally required. Some applications of economic principles to the public sector Although economic principles were developed mainly to explain behaviour and outcomes in markets, most of these principles apply also to the public sector. In particular, microeconomic analysis—the principles of demand and supply and the role of markets —is essential for developing and evaluating public policy. Some examples are highlighted here. Many more arise in later chapters. Scarcity and opportunity cost. All economics is concerned with scarcity. Scarcity implies Opportunity cost choice and choice implies opportunity cost. A consumer chooses a good because she believ es The value of output or leisure forgone that its value exceeds that of the good forgone (the opportunity cost). Nearly all public policy by using a resource involves an opportunity cost. Public expenditure on one service reduces it on another. in one way rather Regulations to protect the environment almost always involve forgoing some other good s. than another The concept, and estimation, of opportunity cost are fundamental to public policy. The value of trade. Trade is the basis for extracting gains from markets. When parties trade in factor or product markets, both parties to the trade expect to gain. Similar gains occur in regional or international trade. Trade between regions or between countries can make each region or country better off and the households in each region and country on average better off. However, issues arise when third parties lose out as they may do (see Chapter 34). The role of incentives. Incentives matter in the public sector as they do in the private. Consider Adam Smith’s description of university teaching 200 years ago: It is in the interest of every man to live at much as ease as he can; and if his emoluments are to be precisely the same, whether he does or does not perform some very laborious duty, it is certainly his interest … either to neglect it altogether, or if he is subject to some authority which will not suffer him to do this, to perform it in as careless and slovenly manner as the authority will permit.25 25 Smith (ibid., p. 718). Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 17 The economic analysis of government recognises that politicians and public servants are guided by private motives as well as by social ideals. The role of prices. Pricing principles apply to many public sector activities, including to non-marketed goods. When there is no price, there is almost always excess demand, as occurs for most health care services and urban roads. On the other hand, the supply of factors of production generally falls with lower prices. Thus taxes that reduce take-home income usually reduce labour supply. But price theory also tells us that all price changes can be decomposed into a substitution (relative price) effect and an income effect and that these may have opposite effects on labour supply. The analysis of taxation requires an understanding of how individuals react to changes in prices. The principles of efficient production. These principles apply to public production as to private. The efficient use of factors of production requires that they be employed up to the point where the value of their marginal product equals their marginal cost. Also, the division of labour (specialisation) generally increases efficiency. These principles should inform public methods of production as they do private methods. Working with markets. Governments should generally work with markets rather than against them. Markets represent powerful forces of demand and supply. Government attempts to control interest rates are a classic example of futile attempts to repeal the law of markets. As Adam Smith observed: In some countries the interest of money has been prohibited by law … This regulation, instead of preventing, has been found from experience to increase the evil of usury; the debtor being obliged to pay not only for the use of money, but for the risk which his creditor runs by accepting compensation for that use. He is obliged … to insure his creditors from the penalties of usury … No law can reduce the common rate of interest below the lowest ordinary market rate.26 More positively, governments can use market instruments, notably taxes and subsidies, to bring about desired policy outcomes, for example to control pollution or to encourage private health insurance. Market instruments often achieve desired policy outcomes more effectively than regulations (see, for example, Chapter 13). Social Welfare. Certainly, determining public policy is considerably more complex than Social welfare explaining private actions. To explain private decisions, economists assume that individuals The collective welfare aim to maximise their utility and that firms maximise profits. In assessing public policy, the of society based on the over-riding objective is assumed to be to maximise social welfare, which is assumed in turn to welfare of the depend in some complex way on the welfare of all individuals in the community. The members of that objective of maximising social welfare in one or other form underlies all economic evaluation society of public policy (see Chapters 7 and 8). Rational decision making. Rational decision making in the public sphere, as in the private, requires that decisions be based on marginal benefit and cost. Firms maximise profits by producing up to the point where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. Consumers maximise welfare by consuming goods up to the point where marginal private ben efit equals marginal cost. In the public sector, as an optimising principle, government should aim to ensure that the marginal social benefit of policies and projects exceeds or at least equals marginal social cost. When this is not achieved, it is always possible to make at least one person better off without making anyone else worse off. In summary, governments have much more complex social objective than individuals exchanging labour or goods in market. However, most principles of economics apply to the public sector as strongly as to the private. Notably, the principles of choice, opportunity cost and trade, the role of prices in determining demand and supply, the effects of incentives on behaviour and the principles of efficient production apply equally in the public sector as in the private. 26 Smith (ibid., pp. 339–340). 18 Part 1 Nature of Government Summary Government exercises the sovereignty powers of the state crisis in 2008-09, growing inequality and the threat of and can control, by regulation or taxation, the activities of climate change, many people regard government as firms and individuals within the territory it governs. essential to economic prosperity and social welfare. However, the mechanistic (democratic) view of government However, just as markets can fail, so can government. And implies that government is expected to act in the interests there is also wide distrust of government. of the citizens. In economic analysis, the aim of public policy is typically to In economic terms, general government includes all services maximise social welfare, which is a function of the welfare financed by the government budget. The public sector of all individuals in the community. This requires normative includes public trading enterprises as well as budget-sector and positive economics. Normative economics deals with services. what is desirable, which depends on ethical judgements. The major economic functions of government include Positive economics explains how social objectives can be establishing the institutions and rules that allow markets to achieved and the implications of public policies. function, the allocation of resources when markets are Notwithstanding the social welfare objectives of most inefficient, provision of social welfare and macroeconomic governments, the major principles of economics apply to management. government as to markets. These include the concepts of Views of the role of government have changed numerous scarcity and opportunity cost, the role of trade and prices, times over the last 200 years. Following the global financial the role of incentives and the principles of efficient production. Questions 1. What is the difference between the state and the 9. What are some differences between not-for-profit government? statutory authorities and public trading enterprises? 2. Why is the rule of law not necessarily the same as the 10. Which of the following are normative statements? rule by government? Why? 3. What would be the features of a minimal state? Why i. Reducing unemployment will increase the rate of are property rights essential to well-functioning inflation. economies? Explain why legal enforcement of ii. Lower interest rates will reduce the number of property rights may be viewed as a public good. unemployed persons. 4. Are government decisions on what citizens can eat, iii. Redistributing income from the rich to the poor drink and inhale consistent with a mechanistic view of increases social welfare. government? iv. Economists should not make normative statements. 5. What is the invisible hand? How does it work? 11. Rational decision making implies that decisions 6. What are the main economic functions of should be based on marginal considerations. Can this government? What is the basis for these functions? principle be applied to the public sector? If so, how? 7. Was the global financial crisis that erupted in 2007 12. Give some examples of how price theory may apply to due to market failures? If so, what failures? Are public decisions. financial crises endemic to capitalist societies? 13. What arguments can be put for government subsidies 8. Suppose, as economists often do, that the aim of for university students? Are these positive or public policy is to maximise social welfare. What normative arguments? would be the main components of social welfare? Should the welfare of citizens and foreign residents have the same weight in a social welfare function? Chapter 1 Foundations of Public Economics 19 Further Reading Acemoglu and Robinson, J.A. (2012), Why Nations Fail, The Hillman, A.L. (2003) Public Finance and Public Policy, Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty, Crown

Use Quizgecko on...
Browser
Browser