Lea & Webley BBS (2006) Money as Tool, Money as Drug PDF

Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...
Loading...

Document Details

WellManneredLaplace4473

Uploaded by WellManneredLaplace4473

University of Exeter

2006

Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley

Tags

money motivation biological psychology evolutionary psychology economic behavior

Summary

This article examines the biological basis of human motivation to acquire money. It proposes a dual theory, describing money's incentive power as both a tool to obtain other necessities and a drug-like stimulus acting on inherent instincts. The article reviews a range of theories and empirical data on money related behavior.

Full Transcript

BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29, 161– 209 Printed in the United States of America Money as tool, money as drug: The biological psychology of a strong incentive Stephen E. G. Lea...

BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29, 161– 209 Printed in the United States of America Money as tool, money as drug: The biological psychology of a strong incentive Stephen E. G. Lea University of Exeter, School of Psychology, Washington Singer Laboratories, Exeter EX4 4QG, United Kingdom [email protected] http://www.exeter.ac.uk/SEGLea Paul Webley University of Exeter, School of Psychology, Washington Singer Laboratories, Exeter EX4 4QG, United Kingdom [email protected] http://www.exeter.ac.uk/pwebley Abstract: Why are people interested in money? Specifically, what could be the biological basis for the extraordinary incentive and reinforcing power of money, which seems to be unique to the human species? We identify two ways in which a commodity which is of no biological significance in itself can become a strong motivator. The first is if it is used as a tool, and by a metaphorical extension this is often applied to money: it is used instrumentally, in order to obtain biologically relevant incentives. Second, substances can be strong motivators because they imitate the action of natural incentives but do not produce the fitness gains for which those incentives are instinctively sought. The classic examples of this process are psychoactive drugs, but we argue that the drug concept can also be extended metaphorically to provide an account of money motivation. From a review of theoretical and empirical literature about money, we conclude that (i) there are a number of phenomena that cannot be accounted for by a pure Tool Theory of money motivation; (ii) supplementing Tool Theory with a Drug Theory enables the anomalous phenomena to be explained; and (iii) the human instincts that, according to a Drug Theory, money parasitizes include trading (derived from reciprocal altruism) and object play. Keywords: economic behaviour; evolutionary psychology; giving; incentive; money; motivation; play; reciprocal altruism 1. Why are people interested in money? STEPHEN LEA is Professor of Psychology at the Univer- This target article seeks to provide a biological explanation sity of Exeter, U.K. He is the author of more than 150 publications spanning the areas of animal cognition, for one of the strongest motivations of humans living in behavioural ecology, economic behaviour, and human modern societies: the desire to obtain money. We start visual perception. As well as being one of the founders by establishing some definitions. What do we mean by a of modern economic psychology in Europe, he is well “biological explanation”? What do we mean by money? known for his research on pattern recognition and And what do we mean by the motivation to obtain money? concept discrimination in birds, and for bringing together ecological, economic, and psychological approaches in the analysis of both human and animal 1.1. Biological explanation behaviour. Within economic psychology he has special- By the 1950s, the “grand theories of everything” that had ised in the study of debt and giving, as well as the psychology of money, but has also co-authored or emerged in early twentieth-century psychology seemed edited several more general books with Paul Webley. to have become extinct. But with the publication of Richard Dawkins’ (1976) book The Selfish Gene, the PAUL WEBLEY is Professor of Economic Psychology strongly Darwinian approach that has been called, with and currently Deputy Vice-Chancellor at the Univer- slightly varying nuances, sociobiology or evolutionary psy- sity of Exeter, U.K. His books include The Individual chology emerged as a new and potentially universal way of in the Economy (Lea et al. 1987), Tax Evasion: An addressing the Why questions about human behaviour. If Experimental Approach (Webley et al. 1991), New people do something, the sociobiological argument runs, it Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Exper- must be because (a) doing it confers a selective advantage; iment and Application (Lea et al. 1992), Children’s or (b) although doing it does not now confer a selective Saving (Sonuga-Barke & Webley 1993), and The Econ- omic Psychology of Everyday Life (Webley et al. 2001). advantage, it did at some period in our evolutionary past, His current research is concerned with the economic most likely in the early history of Homo sapiens, within psychology of personal money management (saving, the Environment of Evolutionary Adaptation; or (c) the debt, investment), tax compliance, and children’s econ- tendency to do it is a by-product of some other tendency, omic behaviour. which does or did confer such an advantage. # 2006 Cambridge University Press 0140-525x/06 $12.50 161 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug Biological explanation does not imply that human beha- We treat these effects of money as “stylised facts.” They viour is “innate,” “hard-wired,” or will inevitably take a could be questioned, but in this article we accept them particular form. Humans are social and cultural animals, without further discussion. Our aim is to explain them and any observed human behaviour is the product of a par- by reference to other known human motivations, known ticular social and cultural environment interacting with features of human nature, or particular features of the human nature: genetically adaptive instincts are always socialization of children. manifested in culturally specified ways. Selective advan- tage is not an alternative to social and cultural factors as 1.4. The problem a kind of explanation, but if an explanation is to be classed as “biological,” then selective advantage must be Most strong human motivations have two characteristic part of it – even if the behaviour currently being properties, which make them easy to explain in evolution- explained, in current circumstances, confers no such ary terms: advantage. 1. Adaptiveness: The motivations direct people towards, or away from, stimuli of obvious significance for the survival of individuals or the propagation of their 1.2. The nature of money genes. This is true not only of motivations such as hunger and thirst that are related to individual tissue In talking about money, we mean just that – money itself, needs, but also of such motives as the need for social com- money as a distinctive economic institution and its physical panions, sexual drives, and parental care. embodiments in particular kinds of money stuff. We are 2. Darwinian continuity: The motivations are either investigating the psychology of money, not using it as a exact homologues of motives that exist in all or many metaphor for property and possessions (for which see related species of animals, or (more commonly) they are Rudmin 1991) or economic activity generally (for which obviously derived from such motives. Continuity does see, e.g., Lea et al. 1987; Webley et al. 2001). It may not require that human motives should be identical to well be that someone who seeks out money is seeking it those of other animals. Humans hunger for a wider and out for the sake of what it can buy. Indeed, one of the more culturally defined range of foods than do other two theories that we consider here supposes that this is apes (cf. Mennell et al. 1992); human sexual motivations always the case (we call this the Tool Theory). But the are unusually independent of the biological need to repro- point of our target article is that this is not the only concei- duce (e.g., Symons 1979); human curiosity takes us into vable theory, because although the desire for money is scientific explorations that are unparalleled by the explora- undeniably closely connected to the desire for the things tory motivations shown by many other species (cf. Berlyne that it can buy, the two are logically distinct and need to 1960); human politics are much more complex than the be investigated separately. Part, but only part, of that socially motivated behaviours of, say, chimpanzees (cf. investigation is to establish whether and how the psychol- de Waal 1982; 1996). Many of these variations on motiva- ogy of possessions, and of other human motives, leads to a tional themes are informed by, and informative about, psychology of money. cultural differences. But we have no difficulty in under- Although we are talking about money in a narrow, con- standing where these complex human motivations come crete sense, our notion of money stuff is broad. We include from, evolutionarily speaking, and we can speculate in the coins and notes that are at the core of people’s concept sensible ways about how they have become more of money in present-day societies (cf. Snelders et al. 1992), complex over the five million years or so since the diver- but we also include both the so-called primitive moneys gence of the ancestral lines that led to chimpanzees and (Einzig 1966) and more modern ones, such as cheques, bonobos on the one hand, and humans on the other. credit cards, marks in bank ledgers, and memory states Most human motives show adaptiveness and Darwinian of bank computers. Any substance or medium is within continuity in an obvious way. It is therefore reasonable to the scope of our discussion if it fulfils or appears to fulfil talk about people as displaying a “hunger instinct” or a “sex the three basic functions of money: as a medium of instinct” or even a “political instinct” – though we must exchange, a unit of account, and a store of value (discussed always recognise that the way in which those instincts further in sect. 3.1). play out in actual human behaviour is a function of culture and individual experience; they are not instincts in the sense of being inflexible, hardwired micro- 1.3. The motivation to obtain money mechanisms. The motivation to acquire money, however, By saying that people are motivated to obtain money, we is not directly adaptive, and has no obvious parallels in mean that when people live in a culture where money is the behaviour of other animals. Furthermore, it cannot used, money enters into human behaviour in some of be imagined to result from some evolutionary process the same ways as commonly recognised motivators such that has occurred within the hominid period: money has as food or sex. More specifically, (a) money acts as an emerged only within the last 3,000 years or so (Davies incentive: if people can perceive or understand that a par- 2002), too short a time for significant genetic adaptation ticular action is likely to lead to them obtaining money, to its existence; besides, individuals born into cultures they are more likely to perform that action (though they that have never used money quickly come to use it if will not inevitably do so, since there may be constraints they move into a money-using culture. Money, therefore, from conflicting motivations); and (b) money acts as a rein- is a problem for a biological account of human motivation. forcer: actions that in the past led to a person receiving We cannot reasonably talk about a “money instinct.” money are more likely to be repeated (though again, It is possible that there is no biological basis at all for our they will not inevitably be). attraction to money, that it is a pure creation of culture, 162 BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug with no connection to human nature at all. That would familiar ends. For example, humans (and only humans) make it an exception, perhaps even a unique exception, will use time and effort to acquire such modern artefacts among strong human motives. We do not consider this as newspapers, radios, or television sets. The incentive “pure cultural” hypothesis directly in this target article, value of newspapers is not biologically problematic. They but indirectly it is under test since our task is to offer the are a means of gaining information about the environment, best account we can of the biological origins of the money and most advanced animals can benefit from such infor- motive. If that account fails to convince, the pure cultural mation: dogs use time and effort to sniff lampposts and option would be all that remained. However, we cannot chaffinches use time and effort to listen to one another’s leave culture out of our account, because human instincts songs. The biological value of information has been are always manifested in a cultural context. Much empirical formally analysed in studies of group foraging in many and theoretical work on the human interest in money has species of vertebrate (e.g., Mesterton-Gibbons & been done within the culture-dominated sciences of Dugatkin 1999; Ward & Zahavi 1973), and operant sociology and anthropology. We will draw on data from psychologists have shown that information may function these sources throughout this article, and in particular we as an effective reward in nonhumans (e.g., Catania 1975; will return to those analyses when we come to offer a Hendry 1969b), though only when it is correlated with a synthetic account of the money motive (sect. 5). reduction in the delay before reward (Case & Fantino 1981). Similarly, many mammals seek out shelter to 1.5. Previous work spend the inactive period of their daily cycles and to hide their developing offspring; many manufacture shel- Despite the obvious power of the money motive, money has ters for such purposes; badgers dig setts, beavers build been given little attention by psychologists writing about dams, and chimpanzees weave nests. None use bricks, human motivation. There are no chapters devoted to it in mortar, and timber to build themselves houses, but we general textbooks such as those by Mook (1987) or do not regard human house building as a biologically pro- Weiner (1992), though extended accounts of specific blematic activity, or the incentive value of building tools psychological theories in relation to money can be found and materials as a biologically problematic motivation. (e.g., Bornemann 1976). Conversely, although economics The Tool Theory sees money in the same light. Econ- naturally deals with money, it has been so little influenced omists have argued since the earliest days of the discipline by evolutionary ideas (at least until fairly recently; cf. that when two people exchange scarce resources, the Boulding 1981) that economists have not recognized the exchange can increase the wealth of both parties (e.g., problematic nature of the money motive. The questions Smith 1776/1908). Money is the most efficient means yet we are interested in have mainly been addressed by discovered of making such exchanges possible. It is not writers who have crossed disciplinary boundaries and con- the only means: among the other examples that have sidered money from an economic but also from a more been analysed are the gift-mediated exchanges that were general point of view: these include economists (e.g., used by the Trobriand Islanders (Malinowski 1922), and Maital 1982; Scitovsky 1976), but also anthropologists the bartering systems by which tools were traded over (e.g., Crump 1981), sociologists (e.g., Simmel 1900/1978; quite long distances in New Guinea and Queensland Zelizer 1989), cultural historians (e.g., Seaford 2004), and (Sahlins 1974, Ch. 6). But these exchanges do not circulate literary theorists (e.g., Shell 1982), as well as psychologists goods anything like so quickly, nor do they produce such a (e.g., Furnham & Argyle 1998; Lea et al. 1987, Ch. 12; Van large social gain in wealth, as money-mediated exchanges. Veldhoven 1985). However, these sources offer general, On this view, money is not an incentive in itself; it is an comprehensive accounts of the psychology of money. The incentive only because and only insofar as it can be present article addresses a single more specific question: exchanged for goods and services. Those goods and ser- Is there a biological reason why money is such a powerful vices are among that majority of incentives that do demon- incentive? The question necessarily assumes that there is strate adaptiveness and Darwinian continuity, and if coherent set of behaviours that we can class as human reac- money is a strong incentive, it is because the goods and tions to money as an incentive, and that they have a single services it will buy are strong incentives. According to explanation. To the extent that we are able to find a biologi- Tool Theory, we do not need a psychology of money at cal reason for the strength of the money motive, we will be all, or we need it only in a limited sense: we only have to giving support to that assumption. understand the job that money does and the human cogni- tive system that enables us to use it. Cognitive psychology 2. Tool Theory and Drug Theory may allow us to understand why a system of a 100 cents to the dollar has replaced Charlemagne’s system of 12 pence Although money is unusual among powerful human to the shilling and 20 shillings to the pound, but such motivators in having no immediate adaptive origins, it is understanding hardly deserves the name of a psychology not unique. There are other examples, and between of money. In the same way as a literal tool like a screwdri- them they furnish two classes of theory that can be ver mediates between our need to connect pieces of wood applied to the problem of money motivation. We argue and the limited strength and dexterity of our hands and that between them these exhaust the possibilities for a arms, so money mediates between our need to exchange biological psychology of that motivation. commodities and the limited evaluating power of our brains. Obviously money is a tool only in a metaphorical sense. 2.1. Tool Theory You can use money as a literal tool – as when you use a Frequently, humans’ advanced culture and technology coin to undo the battery compartment of a bicycle lamp provide us with biologically unprecedented means to or use a $100 bill to light a cigar. Flaunting a well-filled BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 163 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug wallet as a means of social display is almost as crude. But meet the essential definition of a psychoactive drug as such aberrant uses of money are not what we are talking having a nonfunctional, direct, effect on the nervous about in Tool Theory. Tool Theory accepts the metaphori- system that affects our mental state. An instructive cal extension of the idea of a tool inherent in the word example is saccharin, which produces much the same “instrumental”; it sees money as a means to an end. As motivational effect as natural sugars like fructose or we shall discuss in sect. 3.1, economic theory recognises lactose, without being a nutritive carbohydrate. It differs that money has more than one function: it serves as a from alcohol or caffeine in that it produces an instant, unit of account and a store of value, as well as a means perceptual effect instead of a longer lasting effect on of exchange. But that does not undermine the notion of mood, and in the fact that the receptors it acts on are in money as a tool – it means that, like a screwdriver, it is a our sense organs, not in our central nervous system. But tool with a number of uses. Similarly, the possibility that neither seems to be an important point of principle: we money is used for purposes such as social display, social might reasonably call saccharin a “perceptual drug” to communication (Buchan 1997), or social protection note that it has a drug-like action, but not directly on the (Doyle 1998) merely extends the range of uses for central nervous system. The historian of sugar, Sidney money as a tool. Furthermore, it would be a mistake to Mintz, refers even to sucrose as a “drug food” (e.g., describe money, or anything else, as a “mere” tool; the Mintz 1986), on the grounds that its psychological effects idea of a tool is a potentially powerful one, and has been are disproportionate to those of the sugars found in unpro- used by philosophers such as Heidegger (e.g. 1927/1962) cessed foods. and Innis (1984) to provide an account of basic phenom- If we grant this extension of the notion of a drug, we can ena of cognition and perception. see that there are many other stimuli that produce the same perceptual effect as some natural motivator, but are not associated with any benefit to the perceiver. 2.2. Drug Theory Early ethologists discovered many stimuli that resembled Although Tool Theory is the obvious account of the the Sign Stimulus for a Fixed Action Pattern sufficiently motivation to acquire money, tools are not the only class to trigger a response: for example, cardboard disks elicited of biologically unprecedented objects that can acquire sexual pursuit in Grayling butterflies, a striped knitting strong incentive properties. A second class can be briefly needle elicited begging in herring gull chicks, and an described as “drugs.” Just like the Tool Theory, the Easter egg elicited brooding in greylag geese (Tinbergen Drug Theory of money depends on a metaphorical exten- 1951). Although it is to a male Grayling’s evolutionary sion of the core idea, but we start with the most literal idea advantage to court a female Grayling, the butterfly gains of a drug. nothing in fitness terms by pursuing a cardboard disk. Furthermore, many natural sign stimuli will act as reinfor- 2.2.1. Drugs sensu stricto. Certain chemical substances, cers or incentives (e.g., Thompson 1963), and in all cases such as alcohol, nicotine, caffeine, tetra-hydro cannabinol, that have been investigated, the artificial sign stimuli cocaine, and morphine, can all become strong incentives, discovered by the ethologists have the same reinforcing but their incentive power does not depend on their or incentive effects as the natural stimuli they mimic. ability to produce other goods and services. Instead, they They therefore constitute a kind of functionless motivator. produce distinct physiological states by direct action on Like saccharin, they could be called “perceptual drugs.” some part of the body, usually the brain. The nervous Any “dishonest signalling” system exploits this perceptual system contains numerous receptors for natural sub- drug action, and there are many such systems in nature. stances that play a role in the body’s normal functioning, Well-known examples include the chicks of cuckoos or and the existence of these receptors is readily explained other brood parasites eliciting feeding from the host as adaptive. Drugs in the strict sense usually act on such parents by means of gaping behaviour and throat linings receptors, changing a person’s nervous state. But we do that resemble those of host chicks, and deceptive orchids not explain the existence of binding sites for drugs as adap- eliciting copulatory probing from bumblebees and tive. We do not envisage early humans, or our pre-hominid thereby achieving pollen transfer. There are also situations ancestors, gaining a selective advantage by smoking mari- within human cultures that seem to work in the same way. juana. Instead, a psychoactive drug is thought of as a Visual pornography, or the exaggerated drawings used in substance that by chance or by chemical similarity acts cartoons and advertising, can elicit and in some sense in the same way as a body chemical, and which is therefore satisfy sexual or parental motivations (Lea 1984). able to intrude upon the normal functioning of the nervous Such stimuli are only functionless in the strict, system. By mimicking the action of some natural evolutionary sense of function. Within the life of the indi- substance, it produces an abnormal response without vidual organism, they provide the same kind of gratifica- being part of an ordered, functional sequence. The Drug tion as the corresponding fully functional stimulus. But Theory of money motivation asserts that money, too, unlike that stimulus, they are not associated with the incre- intrudes on the normal functioning of the nervous ment of biological fitness that, we assume, drove the system. Clearly, however, money is not a psychoactive evolution of the motivational system in question. chemical, so to develop the Drug Theory we need a meta- phorically extended concept of a drug, just as the Tool 2.2.3. Cognitive drugs. Pornographic pictures mimic Theory of money requires an extended concept of a tool. natural visual stimuli that are instinctually sexually arous- ing, for functional reasons that are well understood in prin- 2.2.2. Perceptual drugs. Alcohol, nicotine, and the other ciple even if the details are open to much debate. But what substances listed above are all familiarly recognized as psy- about pornographic text? Such material can undoubtedly choactive drugs. There are other substances, however, that be sexually arousing, but it does not mimic any stimulus 164 BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug that could be supposed to have an innate effect. Porno- help make the metaphor persuasive. Drugs can be very graphy here serves as an extreme example of a general strong motivators; they are often addictive; an attraction fact: we can be emotionally engaged by many kinds of to them frequently has bad consequences for the individ- text, and therefore motivated to read them. Any such ual; and they give immediate reward where “real” motiva- text must be thought of as a “cognitive drug.” Its effect tors can only do so over an extended period. As we discuss depends on what we know and understand, not on what in section 4, all these features have been alleged of money. we perceive; but like nicotine, like saccharin, and like But while these additional features of the money motiv- the knitting needle that Tinbergen showed to herring ation make the idea of “money as drug” attractive, they gull chicks, it elicits a response without delivering the do not define it. Finding that money did not possess effects that make it adaptive for the organism to make these additional drug-like properties would make the that response. Drug Theory less attractive, but not useless; finding that money never acts as a functionless motivator would 2.2.4. The drug metaphor and Drug Theory. It may seem undermine it completely. that we have extended the concept of a “drug” unreason- ably, so let us recapitulate what we have discarded and what we have retained. We have discarded the idea of a 2.3. Alternatives chemical with an identifiable locus of action in the Could there be other accounts of the incentive value of central nervous system. But we have retained the idea of money which do not fit within either Tool Theory or a drug as a deceiver: a stimulus that is of no biological Drug Theory? Both assert that money gives access to bio- significance in itself, but which has motivational properties logical rewards. Tool Theory covers cases where money because it produces the same neural, behavioural, or gives real but indirect access to such rewards; Drug psychological effect as some other stimulus that is Theory covers cases where it gives direct access to the biologically significant. A drug in this extended sense is systems that subserve such rewards, but in an illusory, any functionless motivator, obtaining its motivational nonfunctional way. Given that we are looking for a biologi- effect by a parasitic action on a functional, evolutionarily cal understanding of money motivation, and given that we adaptive system. are taking as unarguable that there has not been time for It is from this metaphorical definition of a drug that we the evolution of a direct, functional, brain system to derive our second biological account of the psychology of detect and respond to the acquisition of money, the two money, which we call Drug Theory. On this account, theories seem to exhaust the range of possibilities money acquires its incentive power because it mimics the between them. Tool Theory covers the cases where neural, behavioural, or psychological action of some acquiring money is motivated by a real underlying func- other, more natural incentive. Obviously, we are not tion; Drug Theory covers the cases of functionless suggesting that there are biochemical receptor sites in the money motivation. It remains possible that an alternative, brain on which, say, chemicals released by used five- completely nonbiological, model could give a more econ- pound notes react. Nor are we suggesting that money has omical account of the phenomena (see sect. 1.4). This a direct effect via the sense organs, like saccharin or means that only in a limited sense can we infer a role visual pornography. But we do suggest that money can for Drug Theory from any failure of Tool Theory. If “act like” natural incentives at a cognitive level, and its moti- Tool Theory fails, Drug Theory is then the only possible vational power flows at least partly from this. In describing biological theory, and vice versa. But that is not evidence money as a cognitive drug, however, we do not mean to dis- that it is a satisfactory biological theory, only that there embody its action. Although the response to money must be is no better biological alternative. mediated through the cognitive system, it is nonetheless an Money is neither literally a tool nor literally a drug. affective response, just as the response to pornography, or These are both metaphors, which we have used in an fiction, is not coldly cognitive. Cognitive drugs involve hot attempt to capture and contrast two distinct ways of cognition (Anderson 1981). Furthermore, cognitive pro- explaining money within a biological approach to motiv- cesses do imply correlated brain processes. The rapidly ation. We believe that between them they do exhaust the expanding research field of neuroeconomics (Glimcher field of human behaviour towards money, but clearly 2003) has already shown, through brain imaging studies, they are not the only conceivable way of partitioning that specific brain centres are activated in the presence of that field. With sufficient sophistication, it is virtually money (e.g., Zink et al. 2004), and immediate monetary certain that the tool metaphor could be extended to incentives stimulate parts of the brain that are associated cover all the phenomena which we shall conclude are with immediate reward, not delayed reward (McClure better explained by a drug metaphor, and vice versa. et al. 2004). This is the opposite of what would be expected Our most fundamental aim in this target article, therefore, from Tool Theory, since on such a theory money is only is not to establish the superiority of one of these metaphors interesting because of the biologically relevant rewards it over the other, but to deploy these metaphors in a rela- can produce at a later time – a conclusion that is reinforced tively simple form to demonstrate the complexity of the by the fact that in McClure et al.’s experiment, money was phenomena of money psychology. delivered in the form of tokens for an online bookshop, so the final reward could only be obtained after a delay of days. Why should we use the drug metaphor for money, 3. Theories of money and money motivation rather than some other alternative to Tool Theory? The core reason is that a drug is a functionless motivator, and Tool Theory and Drug Theory, as we have developed them that is what we want to assert that money sometimes is. here, are broad classes of psychological theories about the But there are also other features of classic drugs that money motive. We now consider some particular theories BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 165 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug that explicitly or implicitly specify psychological mechan- government may well be motivated to change the value isms for money motivation. We are not attempting an for policy reasons, to the detriment of economic affairs? assessment of the plausibility of these theories, but Bell (2001) and Ingham (2001) trace from Adam Smith, rather characterising them as versions either of Tool through Keynes and other twentieth-century economists, Theory or Drug Theory. These categorizations are of the argument that government gives fiat money its value course ours, not those of the original authors, who might by declaring that it is acceptable in settlement of tax liabil- well have disagreed with them. ities. Ingham extends the argument, suggesting (following Grierson; e.g., Grierson 1978) that the process of money creation has an older history in the use of money to 3.1. The economic theory of money settle other kinds of non-market debts such as bride- A typical economic textbook account states: price and the compensations for injury (Wergeld) that whether money is shells or rocks or gold or paper, in any were common in early Germanic societies. The creation economy it has three primary functions: it is a medium of of value through tax demands answers the metallists’ exchange, a unit of account and a store of value. Of these theoretical questions, and the historical observation that three functions, its function as a medium of exchange is what governments often do interfere with the value of money distinguishes money from other assets such as stocks, bonds is good evidence that modern money is in fact fiat money. or houses. (Mishkin 1992, p. 21) The chartalist account of money is an obvious Tool All that matters, for something to function in these ways, Theory. However, from our perspective, the metallist is that all members of the relevant society should accept notion that abstract money must be backed by real that it does so function. As Carruthers and Babb (1996) goods is a version of Drug Theory. Gold and silver make put it, money is a “self-fulfilling collective prophecy.” good coinage because of their durability. But, according Economists (and others) have divided sharply on what to metallism, nothing can work as money unless there is enables something to be accepted as money. On the one a market for it for non-money purposes. Such a market hand, there is the view – which, as Schumpeter (1954/ requires the substance to be scarce (which is true of 1994) shows, goes back to Aristotle – that money must gold and silver) but also desirable as a result of some either have an “intrinsic” value, or at least be backed by human motive, which must therefore ultimately have a a reliable promise from the issuing authority to exchange biological grounding. In the case of precious metals, it for something of intrinsic value. Money that has this their ultimate incentive value is aesthetic: the desire for property is called “commodity” money, signalling that beauty seems to be a biologically grounded motivation the substance that is used as money, or that backs for our species, and gold and silver are useful in making money, would be sought for its own sake even if it were beautiful and durable objects. According to the metallists, not used as money. It is also referred to as “convertible” money backed by gold functions as a representation or money, signifying that the money substance can be con- symbol of that desirable thing, and though they were at verted into the underlying commodity. Because in pains to distinguish the symbol from the thing symbolised complex economies the source of intrinsic or commodity (see Carruthers & Babb 1996), they were clear that it is value has usually been gold, the view that money must because of the thing symbolised that money, the symbol, be convertible in order to be effective is known as “metal- is desired. It is only because of this drug-like, mimicking lism” or “bullionism.” It is by no means extinct; modern property that money is able to function as a tool. monetarist economic theory is its direct descendant (Bell 2001; Ingham 2001). The alternative view claims that money becomes 3.2. Psychological theories of money acceptable by government fiat, that is, by its designation We review briefly here some historically important as legal tender. Money with this property is called “fiat,” accounts of the psychology of money; they have been sur- “fiduciary,” “chartal,” or “nonconvertible” money. As Bell veyed in more detail elsewhere (e.g., Furnham & Argyle (2001) shows, this view, too, is ancient, but it first came 1998, Ch. 1; Lea et al. 1987, Ch. 12). to prominence with Adam Smith (1776/1908). Fierce political debates between bullionists and chartalists arose 3.2.1. Depth psychology. Freud (1908/1959) commented in Great Britain following a suspension of convertibility explicitly on the question of money, and in his discussion in 1797 (Perlman 1986), and in the United States after of the anal character acknowledged that style of money the end of the Civil War, during which both sides management was one of the most obvious ways in which suspended convertibility (Carruthers & Babb 1996). people differ. Like modern evolutionary psychologists, Both commodity and fiat accounts of money face diffi- Freud recognized the need to provide a biological expla- culties. The well-documented emergence of cigarettes as nation of social behaviour. His explanation for the a money substitute in prisoner-of-war camps looks like money motive was, characteristically, developmental. He excellent evidence for a commodity theory, but it poses suggested that psychological involvement with money two core problems: Why should people trade with a com- must start with its most familiar form, coins, and that inter- modity instead of consuming it, and if they do use a com- est in these must derive by displacement from interest in modity for trade, why does it generally circulate at a higher faeces. Thus, for Freud, and for later psychoanalysts like value than it is worth for consumption (Burdett et al. Ferenczi (1914/1976) who developed Freud’s ideas, the 2001)? To bullionists, on the other hand, fiat money different individual behaviours and attitudes towards poses two problems. First, why should people ever trust money, from the miser’s hoarding to the spendthrift’s a purely arbitrary token? Second, if the value of money self-destructive carelessness, represented varieties of is created by the mere act of declaring it to be legal anal eroticism. This is a basic Drug Theory: money acts tender, what is to stabilise its value – especially as the on the developing human brain in the same way as 166 BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug faeces, with the important difference that it is acceptable 3.3. Money in other social sciences to parents and society at large for a child to take a close 3.3.1. Classic sociology of money. The classic social interest in money. science view of money was shaped by Marx (1867/1932, vol. 1, Chs. 1 –3) and Weber (1904/1976, Ch. 5). Both 3.2.2. Operant psychology. A very different kind of bio- linked the psychology of money to the capitalist mode of logical psychology provides a further example of a Drug economic production. In Marx’s view, tradable economic Theory. Skinner (1953, p. 79) accounted for money commodities are the products of human labour appearing within his radical behaviourism as a generalised token as “independent beings endowed with life” (Marx 1867/ reinforcer. It is well established that stimuli paired with 1932, vol. 1, Ch. 1, sect. 4) through a process he describes unconditioned reinforcers can acquire reinforcing power as “commodity fetishism,” in which certain compelling and are then called conditioned (or secondary) reinforcers; images come to eclipse the objects they portray. The if the stimuli are tangible objects, they are called token conversion of labour into money requires a double trans- reinforcers. Skinner argued (p. 77) that if a single kind formation (Ch. 3, sect. 2), and therefore a double alien- of conditioned reinforcer was paired with many different ation (of labour into the commodity produced, and of kinds of unconditioned reinforcers, its reinforcing effect the commodity into money). For Marx, this abstraction, would become independent of deprivation of any of or alienation, of perceived value from its origins in them. Operant psychologists have seen this process as pro- human labour is a necessary step in the historical develop- viding a good account of the reinforcing power of money. ment of a modern capitalist economy. Although lacking To a cognitive psychologist, the token reinforcement technical psychological input, Marx’s account is plainly a would be seen as a means to an end, and a conditioned theory about the psychology of money, and in our terms reinforcement theory of money would be a version of it is a clear example of a Drug Theory; a “fetish” is a Tool Theory. But within a radically behaviourist account, very reasonable description of a “functionless motivation,” the incentive power of tokens, and hence of money, and incorporates well the notion of deception that is at the derives from mere association with the goods and services core of the drug metaphor. Weber also saw the accumu- it can buy; behaviour is not to be explained by supposing lation of money as essential to the development of capital- that organisms understand causal relations. Skinner is ism, though in his account accumulation flows not from deliberately agnostic about the brain mechanisms of desire, but from the paradoxical way in which Protestant- reinforcement processes, but it is clear that, however ism equated working at worldly callings with virtue while unconditioned reinforcers act, conditioned reinforcers disallowing consumption. This view leads to a Drug must act in the same way, marking Skinner’s theory as a Theory more by default: since the tool use of money is pure Drug Theory. Skinner’s is not the only behaviourist disallowed, money can only be sought for its own sake, account of secondary or conditioned reinforcement (see even though, as Weber recognised, it is not within the collections edited by Hendry 1969a and Wike 1966), human nature to do so (cf. Needleman 1994, pp. 143 –44). though it is the one that has been applied most explicitly These classical views are capable of wider application to explain behaviour towards money. However, other than the specific economic historical settings in which accounts share the essential feature of Skinner’s, that Marx and Weber deployed them. The idea of commodity the attraction to money develops through mechanistic fetishism continues to be used in modern sociological principles of conditioning, and they too are therefore and anthropological analyses (e.g., Carruthers & Babb drug theories. 1996; Desforges 2001; Snodgrass 2002), and the Protes- tant Ethic has acquired new significance in the psycho- 3.2.3. The functional autonomy of drives. A similar metric analysis of behaviour towards money (Furnham approach to money comes from social and personality 1990). But long before the recent period, a wider view psychology. Allport (1937) coined the phrase “functional of the sociology of money had been taken by Simmel autonomy” to describe motives that emerge from antece- (1900/1978) in his major work, Philosophie des Geldes dent systems but become independent of them, so that (The Philosophy of Money). Simmel explored “just about the link with the original motive is historical and not func- every conceivable topic connected to money” (Deflem tional and “‘young’ systems may become stronger than the 2003). He agreed with Marx in seeing money as an instru- older systems” (p. 363). Money can be seen as a good ment of alienation, but he did not see it solely in the example of this process. This too is a kind of Drug context of the emergence of capitalism. For Simmel, it is Theory: though the motive to acquire money is a self- money itself, not capitalism, that transforms goods into sustaining system, its origins are in more basic motives commodities. Money is both the means and the symbol and it presumably acts on the brain in the same way as of the process by which in modern society impersonal, the comforts that it procures. quantitative social relations between autonomous individ- uals replace the determinant relations imposed by 3.2.4. Cognitive development and money. As Webley traditional society. Simmel was specific about money (2004) explains, Piagetians have proposed that children’s motivation: normally money is not a purpose in itself, understanding of money passes through a series of but it has infinite capacities of application in exchange stages. The number of stages proposed has varied, but in relations, and so it becomes desired for itself. In our all cases the notion is that children are, step by step, learn- terms, we can see here both an assertion of Tool Theory ing how to operate within the economy of adults and how and an assertion of its inadequacy, and the need for to use its institutions, especially money. This approach some kind of Drug Theory. This is most obvious in the clearly focuses on the instrumental use of money, and extreme case: “For the miser, all other goods lie at the thus qualifies as a Tool Theory. periphery of existence and from each of them a straight BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 167 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug road leads to the centre, to money. The whole specific that its representation by a commodity is merely contin- sense of enjoyment and power would be misinterpreted gent; for him, money stuff always symbolises abstract if one were to reverse this direction and wished to lead money. But he is at one with Zelizer and other sociologists it back again from the terminal point to the periphery” of money in rejecting the simple economic view that (Simmel 1900/1978, p. 245). “money is what money does.” From a different back- Although Simmel was a significant figure in the history ground comes the striking hypothesis of Seaford (2004) of sociology, he had relatively little immediate influence; that it was the invention of coinage that enabled pre- for example, Philosophie des Geldes was not translated Socratic Greek metaphysicians to conceive of impersonal into English until nearly 80 years after its first publication. universal forces: on this view, money can actually be said The major development of social science thinking about to give birth to abstract symbolic thought (see also Shell money in the early twentieth century came instead from 1982). anthropology, with the work of Malinowski (e.g., Mali- The sense that money is essentially a symbol, perhaps nowski 1922) and, in particular, Mauss (1925/1954) on multiply symbolic (cf. Lea et al. 1987, Ch. 12), seems gift exchanges in non-Western cultures. These ethno- hard to reconcile with any kind of biological analysis of graphic studies supplied an empirical basis, lacking in money motivation; it leads, furthermore, to a cognitive the classic sociologists’ work, for assertions about what rather than a motivational analysis of behaviour towards exchange might be like in the absence of money. They money. We will return later (sect. 5.2) to the question of showed that exchange can take place without money – whether there is a fundamental conflict between this but also that it is distinctly different from exchange in a kind of social-cognitive theory of money and our attempt modern economy. They thus tended to confirm that to construct a biological account. Within the confines of money is not just a neutral tool, but an institution with a our current account, however, we need to classify the transformative potential. modern sociological theories. Clearly they go beyond the Even from this brief survey, it can be seen that there are simple notion of money as a tool for economic exchange, many different nuances within the classic sociological and but they do not align in an obvious way with what we anthropological analyses of money. However, these ana- have called Drug Theory. Rather, modern sociology lyses share a rejection of a purely economic account – tends to see money as a tool, but as a tool for more than not necessarily as wrong, but certainly as inadequate. In exchange, and, as we have already noted, that idea is expli- different ways, they see its invention or introduction as cit in several modern social accounts of money function; corrupting or transforming previous patterns of exchange; see, for example, Buchan (1997). In the final section of but even if money diminishes the social content of this target article (sect. 5.2), however, we shall argue exchanges, it does not abolish it. As a result, money is instead that the modern sociological account should be sought for reasons that go beyond its instrumental func- classified as a Drug Theory, because its conclusions paral- tion. To varying degrees and in differing ways, therefore, lel those of the specific version of Drug Theory we develop these classic sociological accounts are versions of Drug there. At this point, we merely note that if money is sought Theory. for the meanings it carries, that allows for a disconnection between those meanings and the reality that is believed to 3.3.2. Modern sociology of money. Recent decades have underlie them, and thus creates an opening for the decep- seen a revival of interest in the sociology of money, often tive processes that characterize Drug Theories. involving a fusion of ideas from classic sociological theory (especially that of Simmel) with more recent anthropological data. Important contributors to the 3.4. Summary modern sociological theory of money include Carruthers This brief survey has shown that a number of leading the- (e.g. Carruthers & Espeland 1998), Dodd (1994), Doyle ories of money in psychology and other social sciences are, (e.g., 2001), Ingham (e.g., 1996; 2001), Singh (e.g., in terms of the metaphorical dichotomy we have drawn up, 1996), and Zelizer (e.g., 1994). Less strictly academic best classified as Drug Theories. However, we have not accounts such as those of Buchan (1997), Millman found a simple economics versus psychology opposition. (1991), and Needleman (1994) have also contributed to Surprisingly, the most conservative economic theory of the modern view of the place of money in society. money (metallism) appears to be a Drug Theory, while These writings cover many aspects of money other than at least one much-used psychological theory is clearly of the motivation to acquire it, so a full review of them would the Tool Theory type, and modern sociological approaches be beyond the scope of this target article. A recurring may be best described as “sophisticated tool” theories. theme within them, however, is the social interactionist perspective, resulting in a tension between two pervading ideas. On the one hand is the notion that money anon- 4. The empirical psychology of money ymizes social interactions, and on the other is the recog- nition that money is imbued with social meaning and Modern approaches to the psychology of money have been thereby links things and people together (Newton 2003). strongly affected by the emergence of the specialised sub- Zelizer, who has taken a less hostile and pessimistic view disciplines of economic psychology and behavioural econ- of money’s role in society than have many other modern omics. A number of lines of investigation have proved social theorists, particularly stresses how money retains fruitful within the empirical economic psychology of meaning beyond the particular transaction in which it is money, and these shed some light on the issue of Tool obtained or used (e.g., Zelizer 1989; 1996). Conversely, Theory versus Drug Theory. Several of them overlap Ingham (2001) argues that the fundamental nature of with recent empirical work in the sociology and anthropol- modern money is the abstract recognition of a debt, so ogy of money. Not surprisingly, these lines of investigation 168 BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug have shown that quite a lot of human behaviour towards Money illusion disconnects the psychological impact of money can be accounted for in terms of what we are money from what money can do. Shafir et al. (1997) argue calling Tool Theory, because this is the “obvious” that the disconnection is only partial, and that money illu- account. In this section, we review several lines of evi- sion in fact arises from people’s struggles to work with both dence showing that something beyond the rational use of real and nominal values. But even a partial disconnection a tool is involved. We argue that many of these exceptional of the motive for money from its instrumental effect is evi- findings are well accounted for by a Drug Theory. dence that a pure Tool Theory cannot be adequate. 4.1. Perceiving coins 4.3. Money conservatism Bruner and Goodman (1947) found that children tend to People frequently resist new forms of money, even when overestimate the sizes of coins relative to other, physically the innovation is quite trivial. When the U.K. pound similar, stimuli. This report caused considerable contro- note was replaced by a coin in 1983, reaction in the versy, and a series of experiments by other authors clari- press was absurdly hostile; and Hussein (1985) showed fied the result, without however shaking the basic claim experimentally that people did indeed behave differently that there is something special about money objects at with the coins, spending them more quickly than notes. the psychological level (Saugstad & Schioldborg 1966). In the United States, the introduction of the Susan More recent research has supported that claim by B. Anthony dollar coin in 1979 largely failed because of looking at how the perception of money is changed by his- public rejection (Caskey & St. Laurent 1994). Current torical changes in the money system and the value of attempts to introduce a dollar coin are again meeting money. Lea (1981) found that pre-decimal British coins with hostility and very low levels of usage; the coins were remembered as larger than the identical coins barely circulate, except for a few special purposes such under their decimal names, devalued by a decade of as the purchase of subway tickets in slot machines, while rapid inflation. Furnham (1983) found a similar effect dollar bills remain in widespread use. The reaction for an obsolete design of pound note, and further research against the euro in countries such as the United along the same lines has been carried out in other Kingdom (see Routh & Burgoyne 1998) is similarly dispro- countries by Leiser and Izak (1987) and Brysbaert and portionate to any economic facts. Indeed, people are more d’Ydewalle (1989). A Drug Theory can account for these agreed about their dislike of the euro than they are about phenomena by asserting that the value of money gives it the reasons for that dislike, a strong indication that their a special status, which interferes with normal perceptual/ hostility is rationalised rather than rational. That is not to cognitive processing. It is not obvious how a Tool Theory say, of course, that it is unreasonable: the euro is recogni- can accommodate these phenomena. sable as both a means and a symbol in the ongoing project of “Europeanization” (Borneman & Fowler 1997) to which many people in the United Kingdom remain opposed. Its 4.2. Money illusion rejection is the rejection of an institution that is literally In the presence of inflation, economic events and choices foreign to them, and thus incapable of supporting the that take place over time can be denominated either in trust that money is required to elicit. terms of nominal values – the actual money amounts – or At first sight, money conservatism seems to give strong in terms of real values – purchasing power. If people are support to a Drug Theory. However, it is not an unlimited influenced to some extent by nominal rather than real phenomenon, and its limitations tend to support a Tool values, they are said to be suffering from “money illusion” Theory. Caskey and St Laurent (1994) produce an entirely (Fisher 1928). Although the possibility of money illusion instrumental analysis of the rejection of the U.S. dollar was for decades dismissed by theoretical economists, it coins. When currencies lose their value because of econ- has now been demonstrated in economic experiments omic or political change, people lose interest in them pre- (Fehr & Tyran 2001) and survey studies (Shafir et al. cipitately, as a Tool Theory would predict. Furthermore, 1997). It is also ubiquitous in ordinary economic life. At not all new forms of money are rejected. Credit and the population level, consumers demonstrate money illu- debit cards have won wide acceptance quite quickly, sion in relation both to the entire economy (e.g., Dowd, though penetration varies greatly between countries 1992) and to individual commodities (e.g., Franke 1994). (Humphrey 2004; Snellman et al. 2001). Nevertheless, Consumer money illusion can also be seen at the individ- some of the phenomena of money conservatism do seem ual level, for example in price estimation in different cur- to call for a Drug Theory. The loss of interest in super- rencies (e.g., Gamble et al. 2002) and in the effects of seded forms of money is rarely total. Anecdotes of currency change on charitable donation (Kooreman et al. people hanging on “irrationally” to foreign or devalued 2004). Money illusion can also be demonstrated in produ- currencies are common, suggesting that money does not cers: for example, in the borrowing behaviour of small lose quite all its power when it loses its function. Further- firms (Machauer & Weber 1998) and in the response of more, although dramatic devaluations certainly do cause independent professionals to changes in state-mandated people to lose confidence in a particular currency, they fees (Mayer & Rozier 2000). Investors, too, suffer from have much less effect on people’s confidence in money money illusion (e.g., Miller & Schulman 1999; Modigliani in general. The high inflation that has characterised & Cohn 1979). The downward trend in the value of non- many Latin American and African countries for decades resident fathers’ child support payments in the United has certainly caused their citizens to lose interest in acquir- States seems to be in part attributable to money illusion ing their local currencies, but they remain very interested on the part of judges, lawyers, and parents (Hanson in acquiring dollars (e.g., De Boeck 1998; Guidotti & et al. 1996). Rodriguez 1992). The collapse of the rouble following BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 169 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug the end of the Soviet Union caused a return to barter in of technology. But money is, specifically, a tool for exchan- many sectors of the Russian economy (Woodruff 1999), ging. Any limitation on its exchangeability is a restriction for lack of any alternative. But in Central Europe, where on its tool use. Economic psychologists have shown that other forms of money (dollars, Deutschmarks, and now money in modern society, like primitive money, has euros) were more readily available, it was these rather restrictions on its use, particularly in connection with than barter that filled the gap. Moreover, although some gifts. In Britain, young adults do not feel it is appropriate forms of “plastic money” have spread successfully, others to use money as a gift for their mothers (Webley et al. have failed spectacularly. There have been a number of 1983), and identifiable social rules prohibit or allow high-profile attempts to introduce “electronic purses”, a using money as a Christmas gift, depending on the kind of “smart card” where the record of money available relationship, and relative age and status of the giver and is stored on the card itself rather than in a central bank recipient (Burgoyne & Routh 1991; Webley & Wilson computer; all have failed to gain public acceptance, 1989). For example, the person giving money as a gift despite apparent technical advantages (Truman et al. must be of higher status, if only by virtue of being older 2003). New forms of money are in general not less func- (cf. Motel & Szydlik 1999). Furthermore, the evaluation tional than old forms, indeed the reason for introducing of gifts, whether by the giver or the receiver, does not them is that they will be better tools for exchange; but depend only on their monetary value (Pieters & Robben they seem to need to show a substantial advantage over 1999). A related phenomenon is the partial taboo on the old forms before people will adopt them. The reaction to use of money to repay neighbourly help (Webley & Lea them is often emotive rather than calculative. We 1993a). These particular social rules are not universal: conclude the people become attached to money objects there are cultures where to give money is a sign of themselves, as predicted by Drug Theory. respect (e.g., in Ghana: van der Geest 1997) or is socially required in certain contexts (e.g., in Cyprus: Hussein 1985). Whatever form it takes, however, there is a 4.4. Money attitudes general tendency to maintain a distinction between Economic psychologists have developed a number of market exchanges (where money is acceptable and psychometric scales that assess attitudes towards money – usually required) and gift exchanges (where money may for example, the Money Attitudes Scale (Yamauchi & not be acceptable), to the point where some market- Templer 1982), the Money Beliefs and Behaviour Scale motivated exchanges may be given the outward form of (Furnham 1984), and the Love of Money Scale (Tang gifts in order to appropriate a different social meaning 1995). These scales are always multifactorial, yielding (Offer 1997). anything from three to eight factors. Although the details A second sphere where money is often an unacceptable vary between scales and studies, the common experience medium of exchange is within sexual relationships. is to find more or less orthogonal factors relating to Historically, cultures have generally provided ways of power and prestige, to distrust and anxiety, and to reten- legitimising the exchange of money or money’s worth for tion and other temporal issues. Tang and his colleagues sexual access, whether through bride price, bride have found separate and virtually orthogonal factors for service, or the convention that husbands should be the an affective component (assessment of money as good or “breadwinners” for their wives and families. But it is not evil), a cognitive component (money seen as an indicator socially acceptable for the exchange to be made too of achievement, respect, and freedom or power), and a starkly, or in other than the conventional forms: to do so behavioural component relating to practical budgeting. incurs the stigma of prostitution. The exchange has to be Furthermore, these factors enter into different relation- cast within the rhetoric of gifts and giving rather than as ships with other variables of both economic and psycho- payment. Millman (1991) argues that this social conven- logical interest, such as job satisfaction, business ethics, tion acts to mask the real financial exchanges that do work motivation, and life satisfaction (Luna-Arocas & take place within close relationships and are exposed Tang 2004; Tang & Chiu 2003; Tang & Gilbert 1995). when relationships break down. Simpson (1997) takes a These results demonstrate a dissociation between the slightly different position, arguing that on relationship instrumental and affective aspects of money. In our breakdown there is a shift of transactions from the non- terms, therefore, they do not suggest that either Tool monetised gift sphere to the monetised sphere, and this Theory or Drug Theory is correct and the other wrong; causes many extra difficulties between divorcing they suggest that money has both tool-like properties couples – even as they seek that shift to symbolise the and drug-like properties, and the two are psychologically social distance that now exists between them. Zelizer dissociated, so that neither kind of theory could give a (1996) has documented some of the ways in which complete account on its own. people in Western cultures try to keep spheres of exchange distinct, using sex as a leading example; Wojcicki (2002) describes the ways in which South African women, 4.5. Restrictions on money use with a very different cultural background, camouflage The primitive moneys of non-Western societies often money-for-sex exchanges as social relationships; and could only be used for certain kinds of exchange, or Knauft (1997) reviews how the monetisation of extra- there might be several different money systems, each con- marital affairs in both Amazonia and Melanesia has fined to a particular class of commodities or a particular resulted in increasing stigma for the women involved. group of people. Such restrictions on use represent a Converging evidence for the convention of separating failure of the tool function of money. It might be argued sexual from monetary exchanges comes from situations that special-purpose moneys correspond to special- where the monetisation of the transaction is actually purpose tools, which are after all common in most kinds sought, precisely because it removes sexual acts from any 170 BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug affectional context. Thompson et al. (2003) document how as a neutral medium of exchange, ways we sometimes want topless dancers in the United States use the fact that they to avoid. It might be argued that the restrictions on money are paid for what they are doing to help distance them- use can also be reconciled with a Tool Theory by taking the selves psychologically and emotionally from it, and from tool metaphor more seriously and pointing out that tools their clients. Prasad (1999) shows that prostitutes’ clients do not have to be universally useful. But the problem use similar mental strategies to distance themselves with exchanging money for sex, for example, is not that it morally and emotionally from the women they use. cannot be done, but that it is not socially acceptable for The sense that there may be exchanges that should not it to be done because the effects of doing it are socially be conducted in money goes wider than gifts or sex. Devel- and psychologically destructive. It appears that money oping ideas from Simmel (1900/1978), Holt and Searls exchanges have side effects, and that these give it drug (1994) list the family sphere, and consumption of religion, qualities. high art, and education, among the areas where people resist “the market’s commodification of the good” that is 4.6. Money in relationships mediated by money. Even this list is not exhaustive: Desforges (2001) documents how Western tourists some- Sociologists and psychologists have shown that money times feel that any monetary transactions at all between often has as a special status within relationships and a them and local inhabitants in “exotic” travel destinations special impact on them (e.g., Burgoyne 1990; Millman render their travel experiences inauthentic. Fiske and 1991; Pahl 1989; 1995; Simpson 1997). Within families, Tetlock (1997) make the point that people do not just access to and influence over money is rarely distributed find it difficult to estimate the value of their children, equally, and this inequality is frequently a focus for dissa- their loyalty to their country, or acts of friendship: they tisfaction, strain, and dispute. Money issues are reliable find it morally offensive even to be asked to try. Zelizer predictors of divorce (Amato & Rogers 1997), and as (1996) makes similar points about bonuses given by Millman has shown, divorce courts (and also courts firms. Thus, there are many situations where money is adjudicating disputed wills) provide many illustrations of not the preferred tool for exchange, or even is not accep- the money problems that arise in close relationships. table at all. Surprisingly, it is often much more acceptable Family financial disputes are not only about money. In if money is replaced by something that is clearly money’s part, they are about the real power that money gives to worth, even something with a precise monetary value buy real goods and services, and in part they are about such as a book token, a gift certificate of defined value more general issues of freedom and constraint within the that can be used only for the purchase of books (Webley relationship (Vogler 1998). But they are also about et al. 1983). money as such. Disputes about money within the family These data suggest that money has special properties can concern the distribution of limited financial resources that are not captured by the Tool Theory. But do they (e.g., Zelizer 1994), but they can also be triggered when give any direct support to the Drug Theory? What seems one partner acquires new resources, disrupting the pre- to lie at the root of these social rules is a perhaps-unformu- vious distribution of power. James et al. (1992) recorded lated belief that to give someone money is to move the how some wives of unemployed men in Britain withdrew transaction out of the realm of ordinary social exchange from the labour market to avoid the marital strain that into a different, economic, sphere, so that what should went with their acquiring the powerful position of the be a gift or a means of thanks becomes payment – and major earner. Money is a potent symbol and channel of that is something quite different. The prevailing rhetoric the power relationships within a family, and because this of most societies is that gifts are given, and sex is shared, is a direct impact of money rather than one mediated for reasons other than material benefit. Gifts and sex are through what money can buy, we argue that it has a the currency of the moral and romantic economy, and to strongly drug-like quality. confuse them with the currency of the material economy is somehow to contaminate them. These social rules 4.7. Sacred and profane uses of money restricting money use could be taken to suggest that money is different from “real” incentives, such as “real” The most systematic recent approach to the psychology of praise, “real” affection, or “real” gratitude, and therefore money is that of Belk and Wallendorf (1990). Using that money is a mere tool, different from the real objec- anthropological data, they draw a distinction between tives it subserves – that though you can in a sense buy “sacred” and “profane” uses of money. In many ways this love, happiness, and truth, there remains a love, a truth, parallels our distinction between Drug Theory and Tool and a happiness you cannot buy (Needleman 1994, pp. Theory. Belk and Wallendorf’s profane uses are the 237ff). We argue, however, that these results show pre- mundane, functional uses of money that fit easily into a cisely that money is not, or not just, a tool. If it was a Tool Theory. But they put forward the hypothesis that tool, it would always be an acceptable surrogate for even modern money can be sacralized precisely in order other objectives. From an instrumental point of view, to explain “some of the more puzzling ways in which money is the best gift of all because the recipient can people behave towards money.” Among such money use it to buy exactly what he or she wants. The empirical puzzles they include the social bar on the direct use of results show that this point of view cannot be complete. money to buy slaves, brides, political office, or children; Money-mediated exchanges are different from other the distinction made between earned and unearned exchanges, and under at least some circumstances, income; the restrictions on the use of money as gifts; people avoid them. Under a Drug Theory, this avoidance gender and class differences in the uses of money; and is easy to explain: such a theory asserts that money is psy- the paradoxes and contradictions in the ethics of money chologically special and that it acts on us in ways other than use. In sections 4.4 to 4.6, we construed many of the BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 171 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug same money puzzles as evidence in favour of a Drug ambiguities that this produces in the lives of low-paid Theory. Like the data on money attitudes, therefore, Brazilian bank employees, who face deteriorating pay Belk and Wallendorf’s analysis supports the need for a and conditions under circumstances where the money dual theory. they are processing is increasingly powerful. Given the Related research includes Oliven’s (1998) examination contradictions inherent in their situation, it is not surpris- of the social functions of money in the United States ing that he found the Marxian concept of money fetishism from the standpoint of an anthropologist from a less finan- useful in describing their psychological processes. More cially developed society, Brazil. Oliven argues that in commonly, people’s work has a direct financial dimension America, money is what Mauss called a “total social which can be given more or less psychological promi- fact.” Oliven argues that whereas in a society like Brazil’s nence. Schweingruber and Berns (2003) have analysed money is seen as polluting, in the mature capitalist the behaviour and attitudes of U.S. students recruited as society of the United States it pervades all social relation- door-to-door commission booksellers, and show how ships and takes over all metaphors, being associated with they had to both involve themselves in and distance them- love, death, blood, semen, food, and God. Again in our selves from the financial rewards that would be associated terms, it is hard to see how money can be regarded only with a successful sale. The idea of money acquired an as a tool when it has become so involved in a society’s almost magical content for them. expression of itself, though the dramatically extended con- ception of the importance of tools found in the views of 4.10. Money addiction philosophers of technology such as Innis (1984) might provide a viable approach. We argue, however, that it is If money is to be thought of as a drug, we might expect to easier to take these wide-ranging social phenomena as find addictive processes associated with it, though evi- evidence of a drug dimension to the motivation for money. dently they would constitute a “non-substance addiction” in the same way as compulsive gambling. The concept of non-substance addiction remains controversial, but it has 4.8. Money and social status been widely used. The idea of money addiction has been Both classic and recent sociologists and social psycholo- put forward to explain some of the oddities of people’s gists have stressed the importance of money as a marker financial behaviour (Boundy 1993; Cameron & Bryan of status within modern societies. To some extent money 1992; Forman 1987; Goldberg & Lewis 1978; Needleman here serves as shorthand for general wealth, possessions, 1994, e.g., pp. 115ff; Slater 1980). Most of these sources and consumption: Veblen’s (1899/1979) original develop- are popular or semi-popular rather than academic, and ment of the idea of a status symbol was much more the idea of money addiction has found little use in soci- concerned with things that money can buy than with the ology or clinical psychology. Furthermore, many of the possession of money itself. Status is established through references to it in fact deal with more specific addictions consumption in non-monetised or weakly monetised or supposed addictions, such as “workaholism” (Harpaz traditional societies as well as in modern economies & Snir 2003), compulsive gambling (Dickerson 1984), or (e.g., in the potlatch ceremonies of Northwestern Native compulsive buying (Black 1996). It is an interesting possi- Americans; see Aldona 1991). Nevertheless, statements bility that all these are manifestations of a broader addic- of people’s wealth or income, in numerical money terms, tion to money, but there is as yet no evidence to support are a common part of discourse about status; nineteenth that proposition; and given our interest in understanding century English fiction is rich in examples. People differ the motivation to acquire money as such, rather than the in the extent to which they interpret wealth as a sign of things that it can buy, compulsions to spend in various status, and indeed the extent to which they attribute ways are not relevant to our argument. value to objects on the basis of their financial cost; the Slater (1980) did consider one case that is more specifi- tendency to do so is referred to as “materialism” and, cally relevant to our argument: the hoarding of money per from Belk (1984) on, reliable and valid scales to measure se, or miserliness. Hoarding in Slater’s sense is distinct it have been developed [see Richins (2004) for a recent from the accumulation of money for precautionary or review]. People high in materialism seek happiness investment purposes, though of course it is possible that through wealth and possessions (and tend not to achieve at the mechanistic level there is overlap between these it; see, e.g., Burroughs & Rindfleisch 2002). This self- motivations, or indeed the many other recognised defeating nature of materialism might lead us to claim motives for saving (see Lea et al. 1987, Ch. 8). As we this area as one that is well explained by a Drug Theory have seen in section 3.2.1, miserliness was historically a of money. However, it is probably better seen as calling particular concern of psychoanalysts. Clinical and psycho- for an elaborated Tool Theory in which money is used as metric work gives some support to the Freudian notion an instrument to assess or obtain social status and happi- that miserliness and hoarding are components of obses- ness. This is not among the functions of money conceived sive-compulsive disorder, and both seem to have some of by economic theory, but it is different from the pursuit connection to compulsive shopping (Frost et al. 2002; of money for its own sake. Grilo 2004). As such, there does seem to be some support for a Drug Theory of money motivation from the evidence on money pathology. More recent clinical 4.9. Money work psychological approaches, such as cognitive behaviour Even in societies that are not as money-dominated as the therapy, have also been applied to money pathologies, United States, the ubiquity of money means that many and as these too would see the pathological interest in people work directly and continuously with money money as disproportionate the money’s actual usefulness, they do not own. Jinkings (2000) explores some of the they would also favour a Drug over a Tool account. 172 BEHAVIORAL AND BRAIN SCIENCES (2006) 29:2 Lea & Webley: Money as tool, money as drug 4.11. Summary users (Card et al. 1983) because it relies on recognition A consistent theme emerges from these very different rather than recall memory. The good tool always comes kinds of empirical research on money. The evidence is with overtones of drug, whether it is a tool for data proces- not that Tool Theory is wrong, but rather that it is sing or exchanging. Thus we argue that, though money inadequate, and inadequate in specific ways. In a range certainly is a tool, it is too successful a tool for the Tool of situations, money is found to have a value and an Theory to be entirely right. emotional charge that is not predicted by its economic But the Drug Theory is not without problems. First, the use. In some situations this leads to only marginal phenomena that we have identified as requiring some kind effects, such as the sentimental clinging to a few outdated of Drug Theory are not a coherent set. They could easily coins. In other, closely related situations, the effects are be regarded as a mixed bag of marginal, second-order strong enough to determine the economic policies of phenomena that all have different explanations. This argu- nations. ment, however, only carries force if we are implicitly per- It is one thing to accept that money is not just a tool for suaded that Tool Theory must be the correct explanation carrying out the functions that economic theory prescribes for most money motivation. If Drug Theory covers any for it. It is another to accept our suggestion that its phenomena at all, then it may also cover some of the additional psychological effects can be captured by cate- phenomena that could be accommodated by a Tool gorising it as a cognitive drug. We argue, however, that Theory. It need not be confined to the margins. this analysis is fruitful, on two grounds. First, because it More seriously, Drug Theory is feeble unless we can captures the parasitic, functionless quality of money specify what the natural incentives are that money motivation that characterises many of the situations we mimics, and in this final section we therefore seek to do have described. Second, however, it leads on to an evol- that. For convenience, we refer to the incentive systems utionary account of these phenomena, and of the incentive concerned as “instincts,” though, as explained in section value of money in general, which we will set out in the final 1.4, we mean that term only in the sense of a motivational section of this article. If that explanation is accepted, the system so widely observed that it can be taken to be cultu- importance of the drug metaphor fades; it will have done rally universal, like hunger or parenting. Those examples its job in linking together phenomena and rephrasing the are sufficient to remind us that even when motivations question about money motivation in a form that can be are universal, the way they are manifested varies greatly more readily answered. between cultures and periods of history. Here, we suggest two motives that we believe are universal among humans, and argue that they manifest themselves in modern cultures as a desire for money. These are certainly 5. A synthetic theory of money not the only possibilities, but we are seeking to establish that there is at least some plausible means by which the 5.1. The need for synthesis drug-like effects of money could have evolved. Lea et al. (1987) tried to accommodate what was then known about the psychology of money within a loose 5.2. Reciprocal altruism, trade, and money theoretical framework in which money was seen as multi- ply symbolic. In evolutionary terms, this account is vague A prime use of money, considered as a tool, is to facilitate and underspecified: What is meant by a symbol, and trade. Could trade itself be the incentive that money what selective pressures does it respond to? What that mimics? At first this seems an unhelpful suggestion, since analysis did capture was the notion that money in it simply moves the problem from the evolutionary origin modern society has more forms, and more functions, of money to the evolutionary origins of trade, which is than the simple economic Tool Theory would allow. In also a uniquely human behaviour (see Lea 1994). Division section 4 we showed that modern research in economic of labour occurs in other species, but there is little doubt psychology is uncovering an increasing range of money that its integration into a system of trade is uniquely phenomena that Tool Theory cannot account for. We human; chimpanzees may be induced to barter in the lab- have argued here that these phenomena call for some oratory (Hyatt & Hopkins 1998), but there is no evidence version of the Drug account: money seems to act on the that trade forms any part of their natural social life. The human brain in ways that mimic more natural incentives, problem of the evolution of a motivation for trade, not just by being an instrument for access to them. however, may be tractable in a way that the problem of It would be foolish to deny the force of the Tool Theory. the evolution of a money motive is not. Ridley (1997, Money does have functions, and new forms of money are Ch. 10) has argued, from the archaeological evidence, constantly being invented to fulfil those functions in new that though trade originates with Homo sapiens, it must ways. The range of new forms that money has taken in have done so early, in fact it must be as old as the species recent decades, and the speed with which people have itself; he sees trade as one of the distinguishing marks of adopted some of them (see sect. 4.3), show that the instru- our species. So, whereas the use of money is too recent mentality

Use Quizgecko on...
Browser
Browser