How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? PDF

Document Details

StraightforwardFeynman

Uploaded by StraightforwardFeynman

UEH

2013

Enrico Spolaore and Romain Wacziarg

Tags

economic development economic growth intergenerational transmission history

Summary

This is a review article on economic growth and development that discusses the evolving factors affecting economic development, such as proximate determinants, long-term history, biological and cultural transmission of traits across generations. This review examines whether historically transmitted traits directly impact productivity or act as barriers to the diffusion of enhancing innovations across populations.

Full Transcript

Journal of Economic Literature 2013, 51(2), 325–369 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.51.2.325 How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? † Enrico Spolaore and Romain...

Journal of Economic Literature 2013, 51(2), 325–369 http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.51.2.325 How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? † Enrico Spolaore and Romain Wacziarg* The empirical literature on economic growth and development has moved from the study of proximate determinants to the analysis of ever deeper, more fundamental factors, rooted in long-term history. A growing body of new empirical work focuses on the measurement and estimation of the effects of historical variables on contemporary income by explicitly taking into account the ancestral composition of current populations. The evidence suggests that economic development is affected by traits that have been transmitted across generations over the very long run. This article surveys this new literature and provides a framework to discuss different channels through which intergenerationally transmitted characteristics may impact economic development, biologically (via genetic or epigenetic transmission) and culturally (via behavioral or symbolic transmission). An important issue is whether historically transmitted traits have affected development through their direct impact on productivity, or have operated indirectly as barriers to the diffusion of productivity- enhancing innovations across populations. (JEL J11, O33, O47, Z13) “The further backward you look, have evolved over time. Decades ago, the the further forward you can see” emphasis was on the accumulation of fac- (attributed to Winston Churchill).1 tors of production and exogenous techno- logical progress. Later, the focus switched 1. Introduction to policies and incentives endogenously affecting factor accumulation and innova- W    hy is income per capita higher in some societies and much lower in others? Answers to this perennial question tion. More recently, the attention has moved to the institutional framework underly- ing these policies and incentives. Pushing * Spolaore: Tufts University, National Bureau of Eco- nomic Research, and CESIfo. Wacziarg: University of California at Los Angeles, National Bureau of Economic Research, and CEPR. We thank Leonardo Bursztyn, Janet 1 This is the usual form of the quote attributed to Currie, Oded Galor, David Weil, and several anonymous Winston Churchill—for instance, by Queen Elizabeth II referees for useful input. in her 1999 Christmas Message. According to Langworth † Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.51.2.325 to visit the (2008, 577), Churchill’s words were “the longer you can article page and view author disclosure statement(s). look back, the farther you can look forward.” 325 326 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) back the debate one more degree, a key affecting income and productivity over question remains as to why the proximate the long run.2 We review the literature ­determinants of the wealth of nations vary on the legacy of geographic conditions in across countries. A burgeoning literature section 2. seeks to better understand the deep causes A major theme emerging from the recent of development, rooted in geography and literature is that key human characteristics history. affecting development are transmitted from As the empirical literature has moved one generation to the next within popula- from studying the proximate determi- tions over the long run, explaining why deep nants of growth and development to ana- historical factors still affect outcomes today. lyzing ever deeper, more fundamental A growing body of new empirical work has factors, important questions have arisen: focused on the measurement and estimation How much time persistence is there in of long-term effects of historical variables development outcomes? How far back in on contemporary income by explicitly tak- time should we go in order to understand ing into account the ancestral composition of contemporary economic development? current populations (Spolaore and Wacziarg Through what specific mechanisms do 2009; Putterman and Weil 2010; Comin, long-term geographic and historical fac- Easterly, and Gong 2010; Ashraf and Galor tors affect outcomes today? If economic 2013). We survey contributions to this new development has deep historical roots, literature in section 3. what is the scope for policy to affect the In section 4, we provide a general taxon- wealth of nations? This article discusses omy to discuss different channels through the current state of knowledge on these which inherited human characteristics may issues, focusing on recent empirical work impact economic development. Our discus- shedding light on the complex interactions sion builds on an extensive evolutionary lit- among geography, history, and compara- erature on the complex interactions among tive development. Throughout, we illus- genetic, epigenetic, and cultural transmis- trate the major milestones of the recent sion mechanisms, and on the coevolution of literature in a unified empirical frame- biological and cultural traits (Cavalli-Sforza work for understanding variation in eco- and Feldman 1981; Boyd and Richerson nomic development. 1985; Richerson and Boyd 2005; Jablonka Our starting point is the long-standing and Lamb 2005), as well as on a growing debate on geography and development. literature on cultural transmission and eco- There is no doubt that geographic factors, nomic outcomes (e.g., Bisin and Verdier such as latitude and climate, are highly cor- 2000, 2001; Tabellini 2008, 2009; Alesina, related with development, but the inter- Giuliano, and Nunn 2013). An important pretation of this correlation remains hotly issue is whether historically transmitted debated. While some of the effects of geog- characteristics affect economic development raphy may operate directly on current pro- through their direct impact on productivity, ductivity, there is mounting evidence that or operate indirectly as barriers to the diffu- much of the correlation operates through sion of technological and institutional inno- indirect mechanisms, i.e., through the his- vations across populations. torical effects of initial geographic condi- tions on the spatial distribution of human 2 For recent discussions of these issues from differ- characteristics, such as institutions, human ent perspectives, see Galor (2005, 2011) and Acemoglu, capital, social capital, and cultural traits, Johnson, and Robinson (2005). Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 327 2. Geography and Development Table 1, column 1 shows that a small set of geographic variables (absolute latitude, the 2.1 Long-Term Effects of Geography percentage of a country’s land area located in tropical climates, a landlocked coun- The hypothesis that geographic factors try dummy, an island country dummy) can affect productivity and economic develop- jointly account for 44 percent of contempo- ment has a long pedigree, going back to rary variation in log per capita income, with Machiavelli (1531), Montesquieu (1748), and quantitatively the largest effect coming from Marshall (1890). A vast empirical literature absolute latitude (excluding latitude causes has documented high correlations between the R​ 2​ ​to fall to 0.29). This result captures current levels of income per capita and a the flavor of the above-cited literature docu- series of geographic and biological variables, menting a strong correlation between geog- such as climate and temperature (Myrdal raphy and income per capita. 1968; Kamarck 1976; Masters and McMillan While the correlation between geography 2001; Sachs 2001), the disease environment and development is well established, the (Bloom and Sachs 1998; Sachs, Mellinger, debate has centered around causal mecha- and Gallup 2001; Sachs and Malaney 2002), nisms. A number of prominent economists, natural resources (Sachs and Warner 2001), including Myrdal (1968), Kamarck (1976), and transportation conditions (Rappaport and Sachs and coauthors, argue that geo- and Sachs 2003). graphic factors have a direct, contemporane- In order to illustrate the main empiri- ous effect on productivity and development. cal findings of the contributions discussed In particular, Sachs (2001) claims that eco- herein, we punctuate this paper with our nomic underdevelopment in tropical coun- own empirical results based on a unified data tries can be partly explained by the current set, regression methodology and sample. negative effects of their location, which This analysis is not meant to be an exhaustive include two main ecological handicaps: low recapitulation of existing results, but simply agricultural productivity and a high burden of to illustrate some important milestones in diseases. Tropical soils are depleted by heavy the recent literature. We use, alternately, log rainfall, and crops are attacked by pests and per capita income in 2005 (from the Penn parasites that thrive in hot climates without World Tables version 6.3) as a measure of winter frosts (Masters and McMillan 2001). contemporary economic performance, and Warm climates also favor the transmission of population density in 1500 (from McEvedy tropical diseases borne by insects and bacte- and Jones 1978) as a measure of economic ria, with major effects on health and human performance in 1500, and regress these on a capital. In sum, according to this line of variety of proposed determinants of develop- research, geography has direct current effects ment, starting here with geographic factors.3 on productivity and income per capita. Other scholars, in contrast, claim that 3 As is well known, in the preindustrial, Malthusian geography affects development indirectly era population density is the appropriate measure of a through historical channels, such as the society’s economic performance since any technologi- effects of prehistoric geographic and biologi- cal improvement leads to increases in population rather than to increases in per capita income. For a theoretical cal conditions on the onset and spread of agri- and empirical analysis of the relationship between popu- culture and domestication (Diamond 1997; lation size, population density, and long-term growth in Olsson and Hibbs 2005), and the effects Malthusian times, see Kremer (1993). For in-depth discus- sions of this topic, see Galor (2005) and the recent contri- of crops and germs on the ­ settlement of bution by Ashraf and Galor (2011a). European colonizers after 1500 (Engerman 328 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) Table 1 Geography and Contemporary Development (Dependent variable: log per capita income, 2005; estimator: OLS) Whole Olsson–Hibbs Olsson–Hibbs Olsson–Hibbs Olsson–Hibbs Old World Sample: World samplea samplea samplea samplea only (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Absolute latitude 0.044 0.052 (6.645)*** (7.524)*** Percent land area in –0.049 0.209 –0.410 –0.650 –0.421 –0.448 the tropics (0.154) (0.660) (1.595) (2.252)** (1.641) (1.646) Landlocked dummy –0.742 –0.518 –0.499 –0.572 –0.505 –0.226 (4.375)*** (2.687)*** (2.487)** (2.622)** (2.523)** (1.160) Island dummy 0.643 0.306 0.920 0.560 0.952 1.306 (2.496)** (1.033) (3.479)*** (1.996)** (3.425)*** (4.504)*** Geographic conditions 0.706 0.768 0.780 (Olsson–Hibbs)b (6.931)*** (4.739)*** (5.167)*** Biological conditions 0.585 –0.074 0.086 (Olsson–Hibbs)c (4.759)*** (0.483) (0.581) Constant 7.703 7.354 8.745 8.958 8.741 8.438 (25.377)*** (25.360)*** (61.561)*** (58.200)*** (61.352)*** (60.049)*** Observations 155 102 102 102 102 83 Adjusted R2 0.440 0.546 0.521 0.449 0.516 0.641 Notes: a   The Olsson and Hibbs sample excludes the neo-European countries (Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United States) and countries whose current income is based primarily on extractive wealth (Olsson and Hibbs 2005). b First principal component of number of annual or perennial wild grasses and number of domesticable big mam- mals (all variables from Olsson and Hibbs 2005) c First principal component of absolute latitude; climate suitability to agriculture; rate of East–West orientation; size of landmass in millions of sq km (all variables from Olsson and Hibbs 2005). Robust t statistics in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level.   * Significant at the 10 percent level. and Sokoloff 1997 and 2002; Acemoglu, in 10,000 BC (the Neolithic Revolution). Johnson, and Robinson 2001, 2002; Easterly These advantages included the larger size and Levine 2003). of Eurasia, its initial biological conditions Diamond (1997) famously argues that the (the diversity of animals and plants avail- roots of comparative development lie in a able for domestication in prehistoric times), series of environmental advantages enjoyed and its East–West orientation, which facili- by the inhabitants of Eurasia at the transition tated the spread of agricultural innovations. from a hunter–gatherer economy to agricul- Building on these geographic advantages, tural and pastoral production, starting roughly Eurasia experienced a population explosion Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 329 and an earlier acceleration of technological Columns 3–5 add the two main Olsson– innovation, with long-term consequences Hibbs geographic variables, first separately for comparative development. According to and then jointly: a summary measure of bio- Diamond, the proximate determinants of logical conditions and a summary measure European economic and political success of geographic conditions.5 Both geographic (“guns, germs, and steel”) were therefore and biological conditions variables are highly the outcomes of deeper geographic advan- significant when entered separately. When tages that operated in prehistoric times. The entered jointly, the geographic conditions descendants of some Eurasian populations variable remains highly significant and the (Europeans), building on their Neolithic overall explanatory power of the regressors advantage, were able to use their technologi- remains large (52 percent). These empiri- cal lead (guns and steel) and their immunity cal results provide strong evidence in favor to old-world diseases (germs) to dominate of Diamond’s hypotheses, while suggesting other regions in modern times—including that the geographic component of the story regions that did not enjoy the original geo- is empirically more relevant than the bio- graphic advantages of Eurasia. logical component. Column 6 goes further in In order to test Diamond’s hypotheses, the attempt to control for the effect of post- Olsson and Hibbs (2005) provide an empiri- 1500 population movements, by restrict- cal analysis of the relation between initial ing the sample to the Old World (defined biogeographic endowments and contempo- as all ­countries minus the Americas and rary levels of development.4 They use several Oceania). The effect of geography now rises geographic and biological variables: the size to 64 percent—again highly consistent with of continents, their major directional axis Diamond’s idea that biogeographic condi- (extent of East­–West orientation), climatic tions matter mostly in the Old World.6 factors, and initial biological conditions (the number of animals and plants suitable to domestication and cultivation at each location 12,000 years ago). We revisit their 5 These are the first principal components of the empirical results in columns 2 through 5 of above-listed factors. Since latitude is a component of the geographic conditions index, we exclude our measure of table 1. In order to reduce the effect of post- latitude as a separate regressor in the regressions that 1500 population movements, the Olsson– include geographic conditions. 6 Olsson and Hibbs also find that geographic variables Hibbs sample excludes the neo-European continue to be positively and significantly correlated with countries (Australia, Canada, New Zealand, income per capita when they control for measures of the and the United States), as well as countries political and institutional environment. They show that whose current income is based primarily on such political and institutional measures are positively correlated with geographic and biogeographic conditions, extractive wealth. Column 2 replicates the consistent with the idea that institutions could mediate the estimates of column 1 using this restricted link between geography and development. As they notice sample—the joint explanatory power of geo- (934), controlling for political–institutional variables raises well-known issues of endogeneity and reverse causality (for graphic variables rises to 55 percent, since instance, richer countries can have the resources and abil- the new sample excludes regions that are ity to build better institutions). They write: “Researchers rich today as a result of the guns, germs, and have struggled with the joint endogeneity issue, proposing various instrumental variables to obtain consistent esti- steel of colonizing Europeans rather than mates of the proximate effects of politics and institutions purely geographic factors. on economic performance, along with the related question of how much influence, if any, natural endowments exert on economic development independent of institutional development. None of these attempts is entirely persuasive 4 See also Hibbs and Olsson (2004). in our view.” We return to these important issues below. 330 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) 2.2 The Legacy of the Neolithic Transition for 70 percent of the variation in the date of adoption of agriculture, and most enter with The long-term effects of geographic and a highly significant coefficient. Column 2 biogeographic endowments also play a cen- shows the reduced form—again, geographic tral role in the analysis of Ashraf and Galor factors account for 44 percent of the varia- (2011a). While their main goal is to test a tion in population density in 1500, consistent central tenet of Malthusian theory (that with the results of table 1 for the contempo- per capita income gains from technologi- rary period.8 cal improvements in the preindustrial era Ashraf and Galor (2011a) argue that, while were largely dissipated through population geographic factors may have continued growth), their approach leads them to pro- to affect economic development after the vide further evidence relating to Diamond’s introduction of agriculture, the availability hypotheses and the legacy of geography. of prehistoric domesticable wild plant and Ashraf and Galor demonstrate that the animal species did not influence population spread of agriculture (the Neolithic transi- density in the past two millennia other than tion) was driven by geographic conditions through the timing of the Neolithic transi- (climate, continental size and orientation) tion. Therefore, they use these variables, and biogeographic conditions (the availabil- obtained from the Olsson and Hibbs (2005) ity of domesticable plant and big mammal data set, as instruments to estimate the effect species). They empirically document how of the timing of the Neolithic transition on geographic factors influenced the timing of population density. The results of column 3 the agricultural transition. They also show (OLS) and column 4 (IV) of table 2 illustrate that biogeographic variables, consistent their findings: years since the agricultural with Olsson and Hibbs (2005), are strongly transition has a strong, statistically significant correlated with population density in 1500, positive effect on population density in 1500. but argue that the only way these variables Interestingly, the IV effect is quantitatively matter for economic performance in pre- larger than the OLS estimate.9 The magni- industrial times is through their effect on the tude of the effect is large, as a one ­standard timing of the adoption of agriculture. This paves the way to using biogeographic factors as instruments for the timing of the Neolithic 8 Interestingly, the effect of latitude is negative. Ashraf transition in a specification explaining popu- and Galor (2011a) indeed observe that: “in contrast to the positive relationship between absolute latitude and con- lation density in 1500. temporary income per capita, population density in pre- Table 2 illustrates these findings in our industrial times was on average higher at latitudinal bands unified empirical setup. In column 1, we closer to the equator.” Thus, the effects of geographic factors have varied over different periods of technologi- regressed the number of years since the cal development, in line with the idea that the effects of Neolithic transition (obtained from Chanda geography on development are indirect. 9 Ashraf and Galor (2011a) argue that, in regressions of and Putterman 2007) on a set of geographic this type: “reverse causality is not a source of concern, (...) variables—i.e., this is the first stage regres- [but] the OLS estimates of the effect of the time elapsed sion.7 These geographic conditions account since the transition to agriculture may suffer from omit- ted variable bias (...)” (2016). The sign of the expected OLS bias therefore depends on the pattern of correlations 7 For comparability we use the same set of variables as between the omitted factors, the dependent variables above, except instead of the Olsson–Hibbs summary indi- and the included regressors. Finding an IV effect that is ces of geographic and biological conditions, we directly larger than the OLS effect is also broadly consistent with include the number of annual or perennial wild grasses and IV partly addressing measurement error in years since the the number of domesticable big mammals, so as to main- agricultural transition, although care must be exercised tain consistency with Ashraf and Galor (2011a). with this inference in the multivariate context. Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 331 Table 2 Geography and Development in 1500 AD Years since agricultural Population Population Population Dependent Variable: transition density in 1500 density in 1500 density in 1500 Estimator: OLS OLS OLS IV (1) (2) (3) (4) Absolute latitude –0.074 –0.022 0.027 0.020 (3.637)*** (1.411) (2.373)** (1.872)* Percent land area in the tropics –1.052 0.997 1.464 1.636 (2.356)** (2.291)** (3.312)*** (3.789)*** Landlocked dummy –0.585 0.384 0.532 0.702 (2.306)** (1.332) (1.616) (2.158)** Island dummy –1.085 0.072 0.391 0.508 (3.699)*** (0.188) (0.993) (1.254) Number of annual or 0.017 0.030 perennial wild grasses (0.642) (1.105) Number of domesticable 0.554 0.258 big mammals (8.349)*** (3.129)*** Years since agricultural transition 0.426 0.584 (6.694)*** (6.887)*** Constant 4.657 –0.164 –2.159 –2.814 (9.069)*** (0.379) (4.421)*** (5.463)*** Observations 100 100 98 98 2 Adjusted R 0.707 0.439 0.393 — Notes: Robust t statistics in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level.   * Significant at the 10 percent level. deviation change in years of agriculture is ­ reindustrial societies, the results in Ashraf p associated with 63 percent of a standard and Galor (2011a), as summarized in table deviation change in log population density 2, add an important qualifier to the Olsson in 1500 (OLS). The corresponding standard- and Hibbs (2005) results. They show, not ized beta coefficient using IV is 88 percent. only that an earlier onset of the Neolithic All of the other regressors feature much transition contributed to the level of tech- smaller standardized effects. nological sophistication in the preindustrial In addition to providing strong support world, but also that the effect of Diamond’s in favor of the Malthusian view that tech- biogeographic factors may well operate nological improvements impact popula- through the legacy of an early exposure to tion density but not per capita income in agriculture. 332 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) 2.3 Reversal of Fortune and the Role of ­evelopment” (11). We return to these d Institutions important questions below. Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2002) Diamond’s book, as well as the empirical address the issue of whether geography may work by Olsson and Hibbs and Ashraf and have had a direct effect on development by Galor, suggests an important role for geog- documenting a “reversal of fortune” among raphy and biogeography in the onset and former European colonies. This reversal of diffusion of economic development over fortune suggests that the effect of geogra- the past millennia. However, these analy- phy was indirect. The simplest geography ses leave open the question of whether the story states that some geographic features effects of geography operate only through are conducive to development, but this story their historical legacy, or also affect contem- is inconsistent with the reversal of fortune poraneous income and productivity directly. since the same geographic features that Nunn (2009) makes a closely related point made a society rich in 1500 should presum- when discussing Nunn and Puga (2007), an ably make it rich today.10 More sophisticated attempt to estimate the magnitude of direct geography-centered arguments rely on the and indirect (historical) effects of a specific idea that geographic features conducive to geographic characteristic: terrain rugged- development vary depending on the time ness, measured by the average absolute slope period. A reversal of fortune would be con- of a region’s surface area. Nunn and Puga sistent with nonpersistent direct effects of (2007) argue that ruggedness has a negative geography on productivity: features of geog- direct effect on agriculture, construction, raphy that had positive effects on productiv- and trade, but a positive historical effect ity in the past could have become a handicap within Africa because it allowed protection in more recent times. However, such shifts from slave traders. They find that the histori- would then have to be explained by specific cal (indirect) positive effect is twice as large changes in nongeographic factors (e.g., a as the negative (direct) contemporary effect. technological revolution). A broader issue with Diamond’s geo- To proxy for levels of economic produc- graphic explanation is that it denies a role tivity and prosperity in a Malthusian world, for specific differences between populations, Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2002) especially within Eurasia itself. For example, use data on urbanization patterns and popu- Appleby (2010) writes: “How deep are the lation density. Contemporary income per roots of capitalism? [... ] Jared Diamond capita is regressed on these measures of wrote a best-selling study that emphasized economic performance in 1500 to assess the geographic and biological advantages whether a reversal of fortune has occurred. the West enjoyed. Two central problems The bottom panel of table 3 mirrors their vex this interpretation: The advantages of main results: in various samples that all the West were enjoyed by all of Europe, but exclude European countries, the relationship only England experienced the breakthrough between population density in 1500 and log that others had to imitate to become capi- talistic. Diamond’s emphasis on physical fac- 10 Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2002) state that: tors also implies that they can account for “The simplest version of the geography hypothesis empha- the specific historical events that brought sizes the time-invariant effects of geographic variables, on Western modernity without reference such as climate and disease, on work effort and productiv- ity, and therefore predicts that nations and areas that were to the individuals, ideas, and institutions relatively rich in 1500 should also be relatively prosperous that played so ­central a part in this historic today” (1233). Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 333 per capita income in 2005 is negative. In the This line of research is part of a body of regression that corresponds to their baseline historical and empirical work emphasizing (column 3), looking only at former European institutional differences across societies, colonies, the effect is large in magnitude and including seminal contributions by North highly significant statistically: the standard- and Thomas (1973), North (1981, 1990), and ized beta on 1500 density is 48 percent and Jones (1988), and more recently Engerman the t-statistic is 7. Similar results hold for the and Sokoloff (1997, 2002), Sokoloff and whole World minus Europe (column 1), and Engerman (2000), and Acemoglu, Johnson, also when restricting attention only to coun- and Robinson (2001, 2002, 2005). In particu- tries not currently populated by more than lar, Engerman and Sokoloff (1997) provide a 50 percent of their indigenous population path-breaking investigation of the interplay (columns 5 and 7).11 These important find- between geographic and historical factors in ings suggest that the observed correlation explaining differential growth performance between geographic variables and income in the Americas (United States and Canada per capita are unlikely to stem from direct versus Latin America). They point out that effects of geography on productivity. In con- Latin American societies also began with trast, they point to indirect effects of geogra- vast supplies of land and natural resources phy operating through long-term changes in per capita, and “were among the most pros- nongeographic variables. perous and coveted of the colonies in the Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2002) seventeenth and eighteenth century. Indeed, argue that the reversal reflects changes in so promising were these other regions, that the institutions resulting from European Europeans of the time generally regarded colonialism: Europeans were more likely to the thirteen British colonies of the North introduce institutions encouraging invest- American mainland and Canada as of rela- ment in regions with low population density tively marginal economic interest—an opin- and low urbanization, while they introduced ion evidently shared by Native Americans extractive, investment-depressing institu- who had concentrated disproportionally in tions in richer regions. This interpretation the areas the Spanish eventually developed. is consistent with Acemoglu, Johnson, and Yet, despite their similar, if not less favorable, Robinson (2001), where the focus is on an factor endowment, the U.S. and Canada ulti- indirect biogeographic channel: European mately proved to be far more successful than settlers introduced good (productivity- the other colonies in realizing sustained eco- enhancing) institutions in regions where they nomic growth over time. This stark contrast faced favorable biogeographic conditions in performance suggests that factor endow- (low mortality rates), and bad institutions ment alone cannot explain the diversity of in regions where they faced unfavorable outcomes” (Engerman and Sokoloff 1997, biogeographic conditions (high mortality 260). Their central hypothesis was that dif- rates).12 ferences in factor endowments across New World colonies played a key role in explain- ing different growth patterns after 1800, but 11 To define whether a country’s population today is that those effects were indirect. Different composed of more than 50 percent of descendents of its factor endowments created “substantial dif- 1500 population we rely on the World Migration Matrix ferences in the degree of inequality in wealth, of Putterman and Weil (2010), which we discuss in much greater detail in section 3. 12 For a critical reassessment of the empirical strategy (2012). See Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2012) for in Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001), see Albouy a reply. 334 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) Table 3 Reversal of Fortune (Dependent variable: log per capita income, 2005; estimator: OLS) Not Former Former Former Former European European Whole Europe European European Non colony, Non Colony, Sample: World Only Colony Colony Indigenous Indigenous Indigenous Indigenous (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) With European Countries Log of 0.027 0.117 0.170 0.193 b b b b population (0.389) (1.276) (2.045)** (2.385)** density, year 1500 Beta coeffi- 3.26% 22.76% 22.34% 20.00% cient on 1500 density Observations 171 35 73 138 2 R 0.001 0.052 0.050 0.040 Without European Countries Log of –0.246 –0.393 –0.030 –0.232 –0.117 –0.371 –0.232 a population (3.304)*** (7.093)*** (0.184) (2.045)** (1.112) (4.027)*** (2.740)** density, year 1500 Beta coeffi- –27.77% –47.88% –3.08% –32.81% –11.72% –51.69% –26.19% cient on 1500 density Observations 136 98 38 33 103 28 70 2 R 0.077 0.229 0.001 0.108 0.014 0.267 0.069 Notes: All regressions include a constant term (estimates not reported). Robust t statistics in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level.   * Significant at the 10 percent level. a   Empty sample. b   No European countries in sample, regression results identical to those in the bottom panel. human capital, and political power,” which, value and economies of scale ended up with in turn, were embodied in persistent societal unequal slave economies in the hands of a traits and institutions. Societies that were small elite, implementing policies and insti- endowed with climate and soil conditions tutions that perpetuated such inequality, well-suited for growing sugar, coffee, rice, lowering incentives for investment and inno- tobacco, and other crops with high m ­ arket vation. In contrast, a more equal distribution Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 335 of wealth and power emerged in societies after the discovery of the New World, and with small-scale crops (grain and livestock), now constitute large portions of these coun- with beneficial consequences for long-term tries’ populations—either European coloniz- economic performance. ers (e.g., in North America and Oceania) or An alternative to the institutional explana- African slaves (e.g., in the Caribbean). tion for the reversal of fortune is rooted in These regularities suggest that the broader the composition of world populations. For features of a population, rather than institu- while Europeans may have left good institu- tions only, might account for the pattern of tions in former colonies that are rich today, persistence and change in the relative eco- they also brought themselves there. This nomic performance of countries through point is stressed by Glaeser et al. (2004), who history. Of course, the quality of institutions write: “[Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson’s] might be one of the features of a population results do not establish a role for institutions. (perhaps not the only feature) that makes it Specifically, the Europeans who settled in the more or less susceptible to economic success, New World may have brought with them not but the basic lesson from table 3 is that one so much their institutions, but themselves, cannot abstract from the ancestral structure that is, their human capital. This theoretical of populations when trying to understand ambiguity is consistent with the empirical comparative development. This central idea evidence as well” (274). is the subject of sections 3 and 4, so we will The top panel of table 3 shows that when say little more for now. Europe is included in the sample, any evi- Recent work casts additional doubt on dence for reversals of fortune disappears: the view that national institutions are para- the coefficient on 1500 population density is mount. In a paper on African development, essentially zero for the broadest sample that Michalopoulos and Papaioannou (2010) find includes the whole world (column 1). For that national institutions have little effect countries that were not former European when one looks at the economic performance colonies, there is strong evidence of persis- of homogeneous ethnic groups divided by tence, with a positive significant coefficient national borders. They examine the effects on 1500 density. The evidence of persistence on comparative development of national is even stronger when looking at countries contemporary institutions structures and that are populated mostly by their indigenous ethnicity-specific precolonial societal traits, populations (the evidence is yet stronger using a methodological approach that com- when defining “indigenous” countries more bines anthropological data on the spatial dis- strictly, for instance requiring that more than tribution of ethnicities before colonization, 90 percent of the population be descended historical information on ethnic cultural and from those who inhabited the country in institutional traits, and contemporary light 1500).13 In other words, the reversal of density image data from satellites as a proxy ­fortune is a feature of samples that exclude of regional development. Overall, their find- Europe and is driven largely by countries ings suggest that long-term features of popu- inhabited by populations that moved there lations, rather than institutions in isolation, ​ ​2​we obtain in the regressions of table 3 are 13 The R commensurate in magnitude to those obtained from com- the ​R2​ ​falls. In general, R ​ ​2​ s are quite low because we are parable specifications in Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson regressing two different measures of development on each (2002). As expected, as the sample expands beyond former other (per capita income and population density in 1500), European colonies, the explanatory power of past develop- and both variables (particularly historical population den- ment for current development falls, and correspondingly sity) are measured with significant amounts of error. 336 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) play a central role in explaining comparative such as by Guglielmino et al. (1995), show- economic success.14 ing in the case of Africa that cultural traits In sum, the evidence on reversal of for- are transmitted intergenerationally and bear tune documented by Acemoglu, Johnson, only a weak correlation with environmental and Robinson (2002) is consistent with an characteristics: “Most traits examined, in indirect rather than direct effect of geogra- particular those affecting family structure phy on development, but is open to alterna- and kinship, showed great conservation over tive interpretations about the mechanisms generations. They are most probably trans- of transmission. A key issue is whether the mitted by family members.” differential settlement of Europeans across colonies after 1500 affect current income in 3. Development and the Long-Term former colonies exclusively through institu- History of Populations tions, as argued by Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001, 2002, 2005), or through 3.1 Adjusting for Ancestry other relevant factors and traits brought by Europeans, such as human capital (Glaeser Historical population movements play et al. 2004) or culture (Landes 1998). a central role in the debate regarding the Disentangling the effects of specific soci- mechanism linking geography and economic etal characteristics, such as different aspects development, as well as the interpretation of institutions, values, norms, beliefs, other of reversals of fortune. Recent research has human traits, etc., is intrinsically difficult, focused on the measurement and estimation because these variables are conceptually of the long-term effects of historical factors elusive to measure, deeply interlinked, and on contemporary income by explicitly tak- endogenous with respect to economic devel- ing into account the ancestral composition opment. In spite of these intrinsic difficulties, of current populations. We review some of a growing body of historical and empirical these contributions in this section. research, focusing on natural experiments, An important contribution within this line has attempted to provide insights on the of research is Putterman and Weil (2010). complex relationships between geography They examine explicitly whether it is the and human history and their implications for historical legacy of geographic locations comparative development (for example, see or the historical legacy of the populations the contributions in Diamond and Robinson currently inhabiting these locations that 2010). matters more for contemporary outcomes. As we discuss in the next two sections, To do so, they assemble a matrix showing recent contributions stress the importance of the share of the contemporary population persistent characteristics transmitted inter- of each country descended from people in generationally over the long run. This litera- different source countries in the year 1500. ture is consistent with anthropological work, The definition of ancestry is bound to have some degree of arbitrariness, since it refers to ancestral populations at a specific point 14 The effects of ethnic/cultural differences on eco- in time. However, choosing 1500 is sensible nomic outcomes within a common national setting are also documented by Brügger, Lalive, and Zweimüller (2009), since this date occurs prior to the massive who compare different unemployment patterns across the population movements that followed the language barrier in Switzerland, and find that job seekers discovery of the New World, and data on living in Latin-speaking border communities take about 18 percent longer to leave unemployment than their neigh- population movements prior to that date bors in German-speaking communities. are largely unavailable. Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 337 Building on previous work by Bockstette, between historical factors and their ancestry- Chanda, and Putterman (2002) and Chanda adjusted counterparts, because outside the and Putterman (2007), they consider two New World, everyone’s ancestry is largely indicators of early development: early state from their own location. Putterman and Weil history and the number of years since the explore how their two historical variables— adoption of agriculture. They then construct each either ancestry adjusted or not—affect two sets of historical variables, one set repre- the level of income per capita and within- senting the history of the location, the other country income inequality in the world today. set weighted using the migration matrix, Their key finding is that it is not as much representing the same variables as they the past history of locations that matters as pertain not to the location but the contem- it is the history of the ancestor populations. poraneous population inhabiting this loca- Tables 4 and 5 illustrate their approach in tion. Inevitably, measuring these concepts our unified empirical framework. Table 4 is fraught with methodological issues. For starts with simple correlations. The corre- instance, when it comes to state antiquity, lations between state history and years of experience with centralization that occurred agriculture, on the one hand, and per capita in the distant past is discounted exponen- income in 2005, on the other hand, are of the tially, while no discounting is applied to the expected positive signs, but are much larger measure of the years of agriculture. While when ancestry-adjusting—almost doubling these measurement choices will surely lead in magnitude. These results are confirmed in to future refinements, it is the comparison the regressions of table 5. In these regres- between the estimates obtained when look- sions, we start from the specification that ing at the history of locations rather than pop- controls for the baseline set of four geo- ulations that leads to interesting inferences. graphic variables, and add the Putterman According to this approach, the United and Weil variables one by one, either ances- States has had a relatively short exposure try-adjusted or not. The variables represent- to state centralization in terms of location, ing the history of the locations enter with an but once ancestry-adjusted it features a insignificant coefficient (columns 1 and 3), longer familiarity with state centralization, while the ancestry-adjusted variables enter since the current inhabitants of the United with positive, statistically significant coef- States are mostly descended from Eurasian ficients (columns 2 and 4). A one standard populations that have had a long history of deviation change in ancestry-adjusted years centralized state institutions.15 Clearly, in of agriculture can account for 17 percent of a this work the New World plays a big role in standard deviation of log per capita income, identifying the difference in the coefficients 15 Germany and Italy, two countries from which many as the Republic of Venice and Prussia), however, Italy and ancestors of current Americans originate, have fluctuated Germany do not display state antiquity indices that are over their histories between fractured and unified states. that different from other European countries. The United For instance, Italy was a unified country under the Roman States overall has a state antiquity index roughly commen- Empire, but a collection of city-states and local polities, surate with that of European countries, despite the addi- partly under foreign control, prior to its unification in 1861. tion of populations, for instance descended from Native The index of state antiquity for such cases discounts peri- Americans or African slaves, that may have had limited ods that occurred in the distant past (see http://www.econ. exposure to centralized states. While the measurement brown.edu/fac/louis_putterman/Antiquity%20data%20 of state antiquity can be questioned on several grounds, page.htm for details on the computation of the index). Due there is little doubt that ancestry adjustment implies that to lengthy periods of unification or control of substantial the United States had a longer experience with centralized parts of their territories by domestic regional states (such states than the history of Native Americans would suggest. 338 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) Table 4 Historical Correlates of Development, with and without Ancestry Adjustment Ancestry Ancestry Log per capita Years of adjusted years State adjusted income 2005 agriculture of agriculture history state history Years of agriculture 0.228 1.000 Ancestry-adjusted years 0.457 0.817 1.000 of agriculture State history 0.257 0.618 0.457 1.000 Ancestry-adjusted state history 0.481 0.424 0.613 0.783 1.000 Note: Observations: 139 while the corresponding figure is almost 22 show that a variable capturing the extent of percent for state history. European ancestry accounts for 41 percent To summarize, a long history of central- of the variation in per capita income, a topic ized states as well as an early adoption of to which we turn in the next subsection. agriculture are positively associated with per Putterman and Weil’s results strongly capita income today, after ancestry adjust- suggest that the ultimate drivers of devel- ment.16 Putterman and Weil also find that opment cannot be fully disembodied from the variance of early development history characteristics of human populations. across ancestor populations predicts within- When migrating to the New World, popula- country income inequality better than simple tions brought with them traits that carried measures of ethnic and linguistic heteroge- the seeds of their economic performance. neity. For example, in Latin America, coun- This stands in contrast to views emphasizing tries that are made up of a lot of Europeans the direct effects of geography or the direct along with a lot of Native Americans tend to effects of institutions, for both of these display higher income inequality than coun- characteristics could, in principle, operate tries that are made up mostly of European irrespective of the population to which they descendants. Finally, to further elucidate apply. A population’s long familiarity with why correcting for ancestry matters, they also certain types of institutions, human capital, norms of behavior or more broadly culture seems important to account for comparative 16 Interestingly, Paik (2010) documents that within development. Europe, an earlier onset of agriculture is negatively cor- related with subsequent economic performance after the 3.2 The Role of Europeans Industrial Revolution, contrary to the worldwide results of Putterman and Weil. Paik argues that the mechanism Easterly and Levine (2012) confirm and is cultural: a late adoption of agriculture is associated with individualist values that were conducive to economic suc- expand upon Putterman and Weil’s find- cess in the Industrial era. ing, showing that a large population of Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 339 Table 5 The History of Populations and Economic Development (Dependent variable: log per capita income, 2005; estimator: OLS) Years of Ancestry-adjusted Ancestry-adjusted Main regressor: agriculture years of agriculture State history state history (1) (2) (3) (4) Years of agriculture 0.019 (0.535) Ancestry-adjusted years 0.099 of agriculture (2.347)** State history 0.074 (0.245) Ancestry-adjusted state 1.217 history (3.306)*** Absolute latitude 0.042 0.040 0.047 0.046 (6.120)*** (6.168)*** (7.483)*** (7.313)*** Percent land area in the –0.188 –0.148 0.061 0.269 tropics (0.592) (0.502) (0.200) (0.914) Landlocked dummy –0.753 –0.671 –0.697 –0.555 (4.354)*** (3.847)*** (4.122)*** (3.201)*** Island dummy 0.681 0.562 0.531 0.503 (2.550)** (2.555)** (2.216)** (2.338)** Constant 7.699 7.270 7.458 6.773 (22.429)*** (21.455)*** (22.338)*** (19.539)*** Beta coefficients on the 3.75% 17.23% 1.50% 21.59% bold variable Observations 150 148 136 135 2 R 0.475 0.523 0.558 0.588 Notes: Robust t statistics in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level.   * Significant at the 10 percent level. European ancestry confers a strong advan- and restricting the sample to countries tage in d­evelopment, using new data on where the European share is less than European settlement during colonization 15 percent—that is, in non-settler colonies, and its historical determinants. They find with crops and germs associated with bad that the share of the European population institutions. The effect remains high and in colonial times has a large and significant significant when controlling for the quality impact on income per capita today, even of institutions, while it weakens when con- when eliminating Neo-European ­countries trolling for measures of education. 340 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) Table 6 Europeans and Development (Dependent variable: log per capita income, 2005; estimator: OLS) Sample with Control for Control Share of less than 30% years of Control for for genetic Main regressor: Europeans of Europeans agriculture state history distance (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Share of descendants of Europeans, 1.058 2.892 1.079 1.108 0.863 per Putterman and Weil (4.743)*** (3.506)*** (4.782)*** (5.519)*** (3.601)*** Ancestry-adjusted years of 0.105 agriculture, in thousands (2.696)*** Ancestry-adjusted state history 1.089 (3.108)*** ​ ​genetic distance to the ​Fst –4.576 United States, weighted (2.341)** Constant 8.064 7.853 7.676 7.195 8.637 (24.338)*** (17.030)*** (21.984)*** (21.594)*** (20.941)*** Observations 150 92 147 134 149 2 R 0.526 0.340 0.580 0.656 0.545 Notes: All regressions include controls for the following geographic variables: absolute latitude; percent land area in the tropics; landlocked dummy; island dummy. Robust t statistics in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level.   * Significant at the 10 percent level. Table 6 captures the essence of these effect on contemporary development over results. Still controlling for our four base- and beyond the effect of European ancestry. line geographic variables, we introduce the In other words, while the traits c­ haracterizing share of Europeans (computed from the European populations are correlated with Putterman and Weil ancestry matrix) in a development, the historical legacy of state regression explaining log per capita income centralization and early agricultural adoption in 2005. The effect is large and statistically matters independently. significant (column 1), and remains signifi- Easterly and Levine (2012) interpret these cant when confining attention to a sample findings as consistent with the human-cap- of countries with fewer than 30 percent of ital argument by Glaeser et al. (2004) that Europeans. Introducing the Putterman and Europeans brought their human capital, and Weil ancestry-adjusted historical variables the Galor and Weil (2000) and Galor, Moav, (columns 3 and 4), we find that years of agri- and Vollrath (2009) emphasis on the role culture and state history remain significant of human capital in long-run development. after controlling for the share of Europeans, However, Easterly and Levine (2012) also suggesting that historical factors have an write: “Of course, there are many other things Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 341 that Europeans carried with them besides provide a message analogous to Putterman general education, scientific and techno- and Weil’s: earlier historical development logical knowledge, access to i­nternational matters, and the mechanism is not through ­markets, and human capital creating institu- locations, but through ancestors—that is, tions. They also brought ideologies, values, intergenerational transmission. social norms, and so on. It is difficult for us to The basic lesson from Putterman and evaluate which of these were crucial either Weil (2010), Easterly and Levine (2012), alone or in combination” (27). This exempli- and Comin, Easterly, and Gong (2010) is fies the difficult issue of disentangling, with that historical factors—experience with the imperfect data that must be used to study settled agriculture and with former political comparative development, the effects of dif- institutions, and past exposure to frontier ferent human characteristics. The bottom technologies—predict current income per line, however, is that human traits are impor- capita and income distribution within coun- tant to account for comparative development tries, and that these factors become more patterns, quite apart from the effects of geo- important when considering the history of graphic and institutional factors. populations rather than locations. These contributions point to a key role for persis- 3.3 The Persistence of Technological tent traits transmitted across generations Advantages within populations in explaining develop- The deep historical roots of development ment outcomes over the very long run. are at the center of Comin, Easterly, and 3.4 Genetic Distance and Development Gong (2010). They consider the adoption rates of various basic technologies in 1000 Genealogical links among populations BC, 1 AD, and 1500 AD in a cross-section over time and space are at the center of of countries defined by their current bound- Spolaore and Wacziarg (2009), where we aries. They find that technology adoption in emphasized intergenerationally transmitted 1500, but also as far back as 1000 BC, is a human traits as important determinants of significant predictor of income per capita development. The main goal of this paper and technology adoption today. The effects was to explore the pattern of diffusion of of past technology continue to hold when economic development since the onset of including continental dummies and other the Industrial Revolution in Northwestern geographic controls. At the level of technol- Europe in the late eighteenth century and ogies, then, when examining a worldwide early nineteenth century. The idea is to sample of countries (including European identify barriers to the adoption of these countries), there is no evidence of a rever- new modes of production, with a specific sal of fortune. focus on human barriers (while controlling Interestingly, Comin, Easterly, and Gong for geographic barriers). The bottom line (2010) also find that the effects of past tech- is, again, that human traits matter, but the nological adoption on current technologi- paper emphasizes barrier effects stemming cal sophistication are much stronger when from differences in characteristics, rather considering the past history of technology than the direct effect of human character- adoption of the ancestors of current popu- istics on economic performance. lations, rather than technology adoption in We compiled a data set, based on work current locations, using the migration matrix by Cavalli-Sforza, Menozzi, and Piazza provided in Putterman and Weil (2010). (1994), providing measures of genetic dis- Hence, Comin, Easterly, and Gong’s results tance between pairs of countries, using 342 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) i­nformation about each population’s ances- and the smallest is between the Danish and tral composition.17 Genetic distance is a the English, where the genetic distance is summary measure of differences in allele 0.0021.18 frequencies between populations across a To properly interpret the effect of genetic range of neutral genes (chromosomal loci). distance on differences in economic out- The measure we used, ​F​ST​ genetic distance, comes, two important clarifications are in captures the length of time since two popu- order. First, since genetic distance is based lations became separated from each other. on neutral change, it is not meant to cap- When two populations split apart, random ture differences in specific genetic traits genetic mutations result in genetic differen- that can directly matter for survival and fit- tiation over time. The longer the separation ness. Hence, we emphasize that empiri- time, the greater the genetic distance com- cal work using genetic distance provides puted from a set of neutral genes. Therefore, no evidence for an effect of specific genes genetic distance captures the time since two on income or productivity. Evidence of an populations have shared common ancestors “effect of genetic distance” is not evidence (the time since they were parts of the same of a “genetic effect.” Rather, it can serve as population), and can be viewed as a sum- evidence for the importance of intergenera- mary measure of relatedness between popu- tionally transmitted traits, including traits lations. An intuitive analogue is the concept that are transmitted culturally from one gen- of relatedness between individuals: two sib- eration to the next. lings are more closely related than two cous- Second, the mechanism need not be a ins because they share more recent common direct effect of those traits (whether cultur- ancestors—their parents rather than their ally or genetically transmitted) on income grandparents. and productivity. Rather, divergences in Figure 1 (from Cavalli-Sforza, Menozzi, human traits, habits, norms, etc. have cre- and Piazza 1994, page 78) is a phylogenetic ated barriers to communication and imita- tree illustrating how different human popu- tion across societies. While it is possible that lations have split apart over time. Such phy- intergenerationally transmitted traits have logenetic trees, constructed from genetic direct effects on productivity and economic distance data, are the population analogs performance (for example, if some parents of family trees for individuals. In this tree, transmit a stronger work ethic to their chil- the greatest genetic distance observed is dren), another possibility is that human traits between Mbuti Pygmies and Papua New also act to hinder development through a Guineans, where the ​FS​ T​ distance is 0.4573, barrier effect: more closely related societies are more likely to learn from each other and 17 To accommodate the fact that some countries are adopt each other’s innovations. It is easier for composed of different genetic groups (e.g., the United someone to learn from a sibling than from States), we computed a measure of “weighted genetic a cousin, and easier to learn from a cousin distance,” representing the expected genetic distance between two randomly chosen individuals, one from each country, using the genetic distances associated with their respective ancestor populations. That is, we do not con- 18 Among the more disaggregated data for Europe, also sider the inhabitants of countries composed of different used in Spolaore and Wacziarg (2009), the smallest genetic genetic groups as a new homogeneous “population” in distance (equal to 0.0009) is between the Dutch and the the biological sense, but treat each of those countries as Danish, and the largest (equal to 0.0667) is between the formed by distinct populations, to accurately capture the Lapps and the Sardinians. The mean genetic distance differences in ancestor-transmitted traits within and across across European populations is 0.013. Genetic distances countries. This is the measure used in the empirical work are roughly ten times smaller on average across popula- discussed below. tions of Europe than in the world data set. Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 343 San (Bushmen) Mbuti Pygmy Bantu Nilotic W. African Ethiopian S.E. Indian Lapp Berber, N. African Sardinian Indian S.W. Asian Iranian Greek Basque Italian Danish English Samoyed Mongol Tibetan Korean Japanese Ainu N. Turkic Eskimo Chukchi S. Amerind C. Amerind N. Amerind N.W. American S. Chinese Mon Khmer Thai Indonesian Philippine Malaysian Polynesian Micronesian Melanesian New Guinean Australian FST Genetic Distance 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 Figure 1. Genetic Distance among Forty-two Populations Source: Cavalli-Sforza, Menozzi, and Piazza (1994). 344 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) than from a stranger. Populations that share distance as of 1500, reflecting the distance more recent common ancestors have had between indigenous populations, is nega- less time to diverge in a wide range of traits tively and significantly related to log income and characteristics—many of them cultural per capita in 2005. The effect rises in mag- rather than biological—that are transmitted nitude when considering genetic distance to from a generation to the next with variation. the United States using the current genetic Similarity in such traits facilitates communi- composition of countries. In other words, cation and learning, and hence the diffusion ancestry-adjusted genetic distance once and adaptation of complex technological and more is a better predictor of current income institutional innovations. than a variable based on indigenous charac- Under this barriers interpretation, dif- teristics, consistent with the results in table ferences in traits across populations hinder 5. Column 3 of table 7 introduces genetic the flow of technologies, goods and people, distance alongside the share of Europeans, and in turn these barriers hurt development. showing that genetic distance to the United For instance, historically rooted differences States bears a significant partial correla- may generate mistrust, miscommunica- tion with current income that is not entirely tion, and even racial or ethnic bias and dis- attributable to the presence of Europeans. crimination, hindering interactions between While these simple regressions are infor- populations that could result in a quicker mative, a better test of the hypothesis that diffusion of productivity-enhancing innova- genetic distance captures human barriers tions from the technological frontier to the to the diffusion of development relies on a rest of the world. The barriers framework in bilateral approach, whereby absolute log Spolaore and Wacziarg (2009) predicts that, income differences are regressed on bilat- ultimately, genetic distance should have no eral genetic distance, analogous to a gravity residual effect on income differences (unless approach in international trade. This was the another major innovation occurs), as more main approach in Spolaore and Wacziarg and more societies, farther from the frontier, (2009), and is reflected in tables 8 and 9. The come to imitate the frontier technology. This bilateral approach offers a test of the barriers is consistent with the diffusion of economic story: if genetic distance acts as a barrier, it development as emerging from the forma- should not be the simple distance between tion of a human web, gradually joined by dif- countries that matters, but their genetic ferent cultures and societies in function of distance relative to the world technological their relative distance from the technological frontier. In other words if genetic distance frontier (McNeill and McNeill 2003). acts as a barrier, it should not be the genetic We test the idea that genealogical relat- distance between, say, Ecuador and Brazil edness facilitates the diffusion of develop- that should better explain their income dif- ment in our unified empirical framework. ference, but their relative genetic distance Table 7, columns 1 and 2 introduce genetic to the United States, defined as the a­ bsolute distance to the United States in our basic income level regression, controlling for the distance between two individuals, randomly selected from baseline geographic variables.19 Genetic each of the two countries in a pair. Formally, the weighted​ F​ST​ genetic distance between countries 1 and 2 is defined as: I J 12​​  = ​∑​ ​​ ​∑​ ​​( ​s​1i​  × ​s2​ j​  × ​dij ​ ​  )​ 19 Since several countries in our sample, especially the FS​T​  W technological frontier (the United States) are composed of i=1 j=1 several distinct genetic groups, we used a weighted mea- where ​s​ki​ is the share of group i in country k, ​dij​ ​ is the ​F​ST​ sure of genetic distance, capturing the expected genetic genetic distance between groups i and j. Spolaore and Wacziarg: How Deep Are the Roots of Economic Development? 345 Table 7 Genetic Distance and Economic Development, Cross-Sectional Regressions (Dependent variable: log per capita income, 2005) Indigenous Ancestry-adjusted Control for the Main regressor: genetic distance genetic distance share of Europeans (1) (2) (3) ​ ​genetic distance to the United States, ​Fst –4.038 1500 match (3.846)*** ​F​st​genetic distance to the United States, –6.440 –4.576 weighted, current match (3.392)*** (2.341)** Absolute latitude 0.034 0.030 0.015 (5.068)*** (4.216)*** (1.838)* Percent land area in the tropics –0.182 –0.041 –0.384 (0.582) (0.135) (1.189) Landlocked dummy –0.637 –0.537 –0.521 (3.686)*** (2.971)*** (3.051)*** Island dummy 0.584 0.607 0.557 (2.389)** (2.392)** (2.262)** Share of descendants of Europeans, 0.863 per Putterman and Weil (3.601)*** Constant 8.451 8.618 8.637 (23.577)*** (21.563)*** (20.941)*** Beta coefficients on the bold variable –23.85% –27.11% –20.30% Observations 155 154 149 R2 0.499 0.496 0.545 Notes: Robust t statistics in parentheses. *** Significant at the 1 percent level. ** Significant at the 5 percent level.   * Significant at the 10 percent level. difference between the Ecuador–U.S. vector ​X​ij​of additional bilateral variables of genetic distance and the Brazil–U.S. genetic a geographic nature: distance. The specifications we use are as follows: | log ​Y​i​− log  ​Y​j​|​= ​β0​ ​+ ​β1​ ​  FS​T​  W (1) ​ ij​  ​ First, we estimate the effect of simple weighted genetic distance, denoted FS​T​  W ij​  ​, + ​β​  ′2​ ​  ​Xij​ ​+ ​εij​ ​. between country i and country j, on the abso- lute difference in log per capita income Second, we estimate the same specifica- between the two countries, controlling for a tion, but using as a regressor relative genetic 346 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. LI (June 2013) Table 8 Income Difference Regressions with Genetic Distance (Dependent variable: absolute value of difference in log per capita income, 2005) Control for Specification includes: Simple GD Relative GD Horserace Europeans Relative GD 2SLS with Estimator: OLS OLS OLS OLS 1500 GD (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) ​F​st​genetic distance, weighted 2.735 0.607 (0.687)** (0.683) ​F​st​gen. dist. relative to the 5.971 5.465 5.104 9.406 United States, weighted (1.085)** (1.174)** (1.038)** (1.887)** Absolute difference in the 0.620 shares of people of (0.124)** European descent Absolute difference in latitudes 0.562 0.217 0.268 –0.369 0.112 (0.277)** (0.242) (0.250) (0.200)* (0.294) Absolute difference in longitudes –0.117 –0.016 0.024 –0.308 0.245 (0.230) (0.214) (0.205) (0.198) (0.240) Geodesic distance –0.017 –0.018 –0.025 0.025 –0.049 (0.030) (0.029) (0.028) (0.027) (0.031) =1 for contiguity –0.536 –0.475 –0.469 –0.351 –0.395 (0.057)** (0.059)** (0.060)** (0.064)** (0.066)** =1 if either country is an island 0.123 0.143 0.147 0.181 0.180 (0.097) (0.093) (0.094) (0.095)* (0.093)* =1 if either country is landlocked 0.047 0.040 0.034 0.076 0.011 (0.089) (0.085) (0.087) (0.085) (0.085) Difference in percent land area 0.156 0.124 0.113 0.182 0.050 in KG tropical climates (0.095)* (0.096) (0.093) (0.092)** (0.100) =1 if pair shares at least –0.000 –0.027 –0.027 –0.008 –0.050 one sea or ocean (0.076) (0.067) (0.068) (0.066) (0.079) Freight rate (surface transport) –0.506 –0.127 –0.162 –0.550 0.078 (0.748) (0.835) (0.835) (0.783) (0.674) Constant 1.211 1.083 1.078 0.984 0.941 (0.161)** (0.169)** (0.171)** (0.170)** (0.169)** Standardized Beta, absolute 19.47 4.32 GD (percent) Standardized Beta, relative 28.57 26.16 24.43 45.01 GD (percent) Standardized Beta, difference

Use Quizgecko on...
Browser
Browser