Competition and Competition Law PDF

Document Details

DazzlingChalcedony9080

Uploaded by DazzlingChalcedony9080

The Hague University of Applied Sciences

Tags

competition law anticompetitive agreements market power economic analysis

Summary

This document provides an overview of competition law, detailing concepts like market power, competitive harms, and anti-competitive agreements. The text also explores the types of prohibited anticompetitive collusions in the context of economic activity.

Full Transcript

**Competition** and **Competition law** - **promotes rivalry between businesses** - addresses risks of anticompetitive behavior and safeguards consumer welfare. **Market power** = The ability to behave independently from competitors to an appreciable extent. Examined in the context of th...

**Competition** and **Competition law** - **promotes rivalry between businesses** - addresses risks of anticompetitive behavior and safeguards consumer welfare. **Market power** = The ability to behave independently from competitors to an appreciable extent. Examined in the context of the **relevant market**: 1. Product market (interchangeable products) Cola/Pepsi 2. Geographical market (homogenous conditions) 3. Temporal market **Indications of market power**: market share, barriers to entry, buying power **Competitive harms** - Joint market power after agreement that harms competition - Single dominant/monopolist firm that harms competition - Mergers of 2 or more firms that harm competition **Art.101(1) TFEU prohibition of anticompetitive agreements**: A. **[Undertaking]** = **entity engaged in an economic activity,** regardless of the legal status of the entity and the way in which it is financed *(Höfner)* - legitimate interest representative function - do not have to carry out economic activity for its decisions to fall under Art. 101(1) TFEU B. **3 types of prohibited collusion:** - **[Agreements ]** = **concurrence of wills** between at least two parties, the form in which it is manifested being unimportant so long as it **constitutes the faithful expression of the parties\' intention** (*Bayer AG)* - **Not necessarily legally binding** - **[Decisions ]** **= any measure taken by an association that reflects AU's desire to** **coordinate** members' actions *(Bellamy and Child)* - **[Concerted practices ]** **= less intense forms of cooperation** - **Practical cooperation** substituted for the risks of competition" *(Dyestuff)* - Must include: 1. Mental consensus 2. Contact between the undertakings 3. The substitution of competition by cooperation 4. Causal link between mental consensus and concerted practice **Art. 101(1) TFEU only applies if conduct has its object or effect the restriction of competition:** Restriction by object **OR** effect -- **alternative requirements** C. [**by object**:] - to be analyzed by looking at **objective aims** of agreement/concerted practice - Restrictive by object if it **at least has the potential to impede trade** between MSs for economic reasons or by hindering integration - Restrictive by object *per se*: **hardcore restrictions** - If no restriction by object (= the object cannot be found to be restrictive) → **[by effect]**: - thorough analysis of effects on competition factual + hypothetical restrictive effects on actual or potential competitors D. **[Effect on Trade ]** - **Trade** = not limited to traditional exchange of goods and services, it is a **wider concept**, **covering all cross-border economic activity, may include pure national agreements** - trade between MSs must be **affected in an appreciable way** to cause EU competition law to apply→ **they should have a minimum level of cross-border effects** ***Presumption of non-affectation* [ ]**(= agreements are not capable of appreciably affecting trade between MSs) if: - Aggregate mkt share less than 5% - Aggregate turnover less than 40M € - applies to ANY restriction (by object and by effect) - a. - Not all cooperations are outright illegal → Focus of enquiry: Presumably legitimate agreements but include some restrictions on competition that could give rise to **anti-competitive effects** (NOT anti-competitive by object) A. ***Horizontal agreements*** - **between competitors =** companies at the **same level** of manufacturing, distribution or retail - These agreements **may be commercially attractive and pro-competitive** if they concern **R&D (research and development), exchanges of know-how, standard setting etc.** - Horizontal cooperation agreements may have legit aims but **can have the effect of limiting competition**: e.g. ***agreement to exchange sensitive information*** - ***Commission Guidelines on Horizontal Co-Operation Agreements*** - Deemed more problematic: interest usually to raise consumer prices B. ***Vertical agreements*** - = between companies operating at **different levels of the production/distribution chain** - Generate fundamentally different market outcomes than horizontal agreements → **different incentives re price setting** function -\> producer interested in setting low price =\> **'self-policing' of vertical agreements =** natural alignment of interests between parties 1. **Exclusive distribution agreements** - Manufacturer gives a distributor exclusive rights to sell in a specific area. - Encourages investment in marketing and services but risks free-riding by others. - EU law allows restrictions but bans absolute territorial exclusivity; **passive sales** (unsolicited orders) must remain allowed. 2. **Most-Favoured-Nation (MFN) Clauses** - Distributor requires the supplier to offer equal or better prices/terms compared to others. - Helps prevent free-riding and ensures price fairness but may lead to harmful price uniformity. - Each case is analysed to ensure it doesn't harm competition. **Art. 101 (2) TFEU Consequences of anti-competitive agreements = NULLITY** - any agreement restricting competition which is caught by Art. 101(1) TFEU **AUTOMATICALLY VOID** unless it meets the requirements in Art. 101(3) TFEU (exceptions). - **applies directly and without notice** (*SA Brasserie de Haecht*) - A void agreement **has no legal effect** as between the contracting parties and establishes no rights or duties of third parties. (*Beguelin Import*) - Nullity **covers all past and future effects** of the agreement or decision as long as an infringement of the competition rules exists. (*SA Brasserie de Haecht*) - The **invalidity is absolute,** an agreement which is null and void by virtue of this provision has no effect as between the contracting parties and cannot be invoked against third parties. (*Manfredi)* - Nullity: **absolute in nature and binding** on all relevant courts (*Courage Ltd*) - Nullity sanction applies to the **provisions of the agreement that breach** Art. 101(1) TFEU. **The entire agreement** is void only if the void clauses cannot be severed or when the remaining provisions have no autonomous legal content (*Société Technique Minière)* **Art. 101 (3) TFEU The legal exception = 'Agreements that are allowed'** A. **[Block exemptions ]** - ***Horizontal block*** ***exemptions*** (HBER) - **R&D Agreements** - All parties have access to results of R&D/ to pre-existing know-how - Access to- and Joint exploitation of results - **Market share threshold:** Max. combined market share **25%** - safe harbor - **Specialization Agreements** - ***Vertical block exemptions*** (VBER) - **Market share cap**: **Double market share cap** (Art. 3) - the block exemption applies provided that: - Market share held by the supplier ≤ 30% and - Market share held by the buyer ≤ 30% B. **[Individual exemptions]** - ***Guidelines on the application of the Article 101 (3) TFEU*** - **4 criteria:** 1. ***efficiency gains of restrictive agreement*** - *cost efficiencies* - *qualitative efficiencies* 2. ***fair share for consumers*** - **Consumers**: "all direct and indirect users of the products covered by the agreement" - **Focus** should be on the overall impact on consumers of the particular product on the relevant market - **The benefit should be passed on to the consumers**, otherwise they will not be eligible for an individual exemption. Benefits must outweigh potential negative consequences. 3. ***indispensability of restrictions*** - **restrictions of competition are *reasonably necessary* to achieve the efficiencies**. The parties should try to attain their objective with as little harm to competition as possible. 4. ***no elimination of competition in a substantial part of the market*** - **protection of rivalry and the competitive process is given priority** over potentially pro-competitive efficiency gains which could result from restrictive agreements' - A combined market share of 70% is indicative of the elimination of competition **Art. 102 TFEU: Abuse of dominant position** - **Dominance alone not illegal -- only the abuse thereof** - Art. 102 TFEU addresses **unilateral conduct** **The elements of Art. 102 TFEU** A. **[Undertaking]** - **Single economic entity doctrine:** does not apply under Art.102 TFEU: a dominant undertaking may violate the competition rules by giving its subsidiaries preferential treatment in relation to 3rd parties. - **Exceptions:** 2. **revenue-producing monopoly** 3. have been **granted immunity** from Article 102 TFEU by the respective Member State. B. **[Dominant position on the market ]** - Test: 1. Defining relevant market 2. Market power, market share, barrier to entry - **Dominance** = **a position of economic strength which enables an undertaking to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors.** (*United Brands v Commission)* - **Indicators of dominance:** i. **Market share - Presumption of dominance where market shares \> 50 % over time** (*AKZO v Commission)* ii. ***Barriers to entry -*** may reinforce market power by making market entry of rivals difficult iii. **Countervailing buyer power** - a dominant position may not be assumed as long as the customers are able to influence the terms and conditions on which they acquire goods from allegedly dominant undertakings. The **seller is unable to behave independently of its customers** - The concept of dominance does not require a company to be very large to be in a dominant position in terms of absolute turnover. On a small relevant market an undertaking with a relatively low turnover may possess a dominant position. The question is if such a market qualifies as a **substantial part of the IM** which is likely to be found where there is a strong cross-border element in the respective conduct. - **Collective dominance =** dominant position **jointly held by two or more independent economic undertakings** in relation to a specific market **-\> 3-stage test** *(Airtours):* C. **[Substantial part of the IM]** - Broadly interpreted → A relatively small market (e.g. airport) may qualify as a substantial part of the IM since it is of relevance for the performance of cross-border services and market integration. → A bigger market may not qualify as substantial if conduct on that market has no impact on cross-border competition. → a market covering the **territory of an entire MS will almost always amount to a substantial part of the internal market**. D. **[Abuse]** → behavior that impairs effective competition from smaller rivals. Dominant undertakings have an obligation not to eliminate rivals by means resulting from their market power; = **weakens competition** → conduct directed at customers that the dominant company could not afford under conditions of effective competition. = **detriment of consumers** - **mere existence of a dominant position [does not] amount to an abuse** → dominant undertaking has to **engage in an activity that negatively affects market structure and consumer welfare and thus is abusive.** - **Types of abuse**: **exploitative** and **exclusionary** (both have various forms) I. **[Exploitative abuses]** = Imposition of unfair conditions on consumers II. **[Exclusionary abuses]** = directed against the *smaller rivals* (competitors) E. **[Effects on trade between MS]** - The conduct does not necessarily have to affect consumers in the EU but an effect on trade between MSs may also consist in a **change of the market structure in the EU**, (for example by reducing the number of manufacturers of a certain product that is mainly exported to non-EU markets) - ***Guidelines on the effect on trade concept*** in Articles 101 and 102 - **General rule:** Unless an 'abuse is purely local in nature or involves only an insignificant share of the sales of the dominant undertaking', it is **very likely that the Commission and the courts will find trade between MSs to be affected**. **[Defences ]** 1. ***[Meeting competition defence]*** **=** A dominant undertaking is **free to compete on the merits** and to react to market action taken by its smaller rivals by appropriate means → dominant companies **do not have an obligation to protect inefficient competitors** 2. ***[Efficiency defence]*** **=** efficiency gains and losses of consumer welfare can be balanced = **efficiencies that outweigh its negative effects.** 3. ***[Objective justification ]*** **Control of Concentration = EU Merger Control** - **To prevent creation/strengthening of a market structure detrimental** to competition - **Pre-emptive (= preventive) regime** that can stop transactions - Prior notification necessary (***ex ante* appraisal**) if turnover exceeds thresholds - **Substantive assessment (analysis):** pro- and anticompetitive effects of planned merger (EC -- SIEC test) - **Mergers may impede effective competition**: changing market structure: firms more likely to coordinate and raise their prices reduction of firms' abilities to compete → raise prices → its implementation may be based solely on **predicting future effects on competition** in relevant market: economic simulations models applied to assess effect on competition - Governed by: ***EU Merger Regulation 139/2004* (EUMR) +** - Scope of EUMR : I. Concentration II. EU Dimension I. **Concentration** a. **[Mergers] = [ ]**A and B merge and form a new company AB - Reduction of the number of competitors - Risk: **collusion/coordinated effects, creating a dominant position** (unilateral effects) - Between different layers of supply chain (production and distribution) - Risk: barrier to entry - - **2 different, but** **related markets** (for example - wine and mineral water = producers) → **Competitive risk**: Both producers sell through the same market (cafes, hotels, restaurants), merged company has higher bargaining power → may foreclose competitors on one or both markets b. **[Acquisition of control]** - Company A and company B, company A acquires 100% of control over B - **change of control results from the acquisition of direct or indirect control of the whole or parts of one or more undertakings**. - Most common way: **acquisition of shares** - **CONTROL**: constituted by rights, contracts or other means which confer the possibility of **exercising decisive** **influence** c. **[Joint venture]** - A and B create a new firm C C is **controlled equally** by A and B, by holding 50% of the shares A and B have **joint control** - A has already an existing subsidiary C, controlled by 100% Following the transaction, A and B will each control 50% of C = joint venture II. **EU Dimension** **Relationship: EU & national merger control** **One-stop-shop principle** **= Concentrations that have an EU dimension are investigated by the EC and fall under the EUMR** → concentrations reviewed by the EC do not also need to gain clearance from EU MS NCAs. **Referral:** between EC and NCAs. Purpose: allocate authority best placed to review merger (eg. if a merger is notifiable in at least 3 MSs → referral to EC for consistent review./ If merger likely to have effects on the national market only → referral to NCA) **Exceptionally, protection of national interests may justify the application of national law** to transactions otherwise subject to review by EC: eg. safeguarding plurality of media -- requires review under MC law AND sector-specific national law. **Substantive appraisal** - will the proposed transaction create **a significant impediment to effective competition**? **creation or strengthening of dominant position** may give rise to such impediment. - **When appraising anticompetitive effects of a concentration**: Review pre- and post-merger market developments Assess counterfactual situation (situation in absence of merger) **Horizontal mergers**: ***Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers*:** **Vertical mergers: *Guidelines on the assessment of non-horizontal mergers para. 17-19*** **Conglomerate mergers:** may result in foreclosure or portfolio effects: merged entity may be able to offer packages that rivals are unable to + entire portfolio of products from 1 source more attractive to consumers **EU merger procedure:** - [***Notification of EC***:] **After:** conclusion of agreement/announcement of public bid - ***[Suspension obligation]:*** requests parties not to close deals before merger clearance has been obtained. - ***[Appraisal by Commission]:* subject to time limits** → if expires without decision, clearance deemed to have been granted - - - - - - - - - - - **Parties may address competitive concerns** identified in the merger review process → offer **commitments** to EC → typically *aim at limiting the market position* of the merged entity through structural remedies → *Commitments become part of clearance decision* and take the form of conditions and obligations. - **Final decisions of EC on merger control subject to judicial review**. **Enforcement of EU Competition Law (public- and private enforcement)** - *Ex-post*, **reactive** **PUBLIC ENFORCEMENT system** - When **investigating**, the EC may require information and carry out unannounced inspections of business premises and private homes. - Main procedural rules in ***Council Reg 1/2003*** NOT in TFEU - **Parallel system of enforcement**: **Jurisdiction to apply Art. 101 and 102 TFEU**: EC, NCAs and national courts to make enforcement more efficient - **EC = key enforcer of EU competition law** - Actors of competition law enforcement must **cooperate (= principle of sincere cooperation)** due to the **decentralized** nature of enforcement - **Supremacy** of EU competition law **[Actors:]** - EC, NCAs, national courts, ECN, EJC (action for annulment art. 263 TFEU) - National authorities also entitled to apply EU competition law + National courts must observe EU competition law - **Coordination mechanism** necessary to avoid diverging decisions of EU and national institutions - **NCAs inform EC before taking formal investigative measures** re alleged violation of EU competition law - **If EC commences procedure**→ **NCA automatically loses competence** - **National courts may not hand down judgments counter to EC decision** → national courts inform each other. - Plurality of enforcement bodies → cooperation → **European Competition Network (ECN)** - **EU MSs - Obligation of national institutions not to frustrate any EU enforcement action** **[Enforcement procedure: ]** **Commission procedure** **The procedure before the EC consists of two successive stages**. In the first stage the facts are investigated. In the second stage the undertakings concerned are informed by the EC of its objections (the so-called 'statement of objections') and are given the opportunity to present their view and legal arguments **EC may launch a procedure:** →**on its own motion** or →following a **complaint lodged by a third party** **Per Reg 1/2003: EC has wide powers of investigation** It may ***require information*** (Art. 18 Cou Reg 1/2003) ***Conduct Interviews*** (Art.19) ***Conduct inspections*** (Art. 20-21) **General investigative principles:** - **Scope of legal professional privilege limited** - only documents created by an external lawyer escape review - **Under the privilege against self-incrimination**, parties have to provide to the EC any factual information it has requested but are under no obligation to explain the purpose of certain acts or qualify their behavior. - European courts hold that the ***ne bis in idem principle*** is not violated by the EC's fining policy in cases of cartel recidivism + each infringement constitutes a new set of facts even if a higher fine is imposed due to previous infringements. - **The general limitation period for cartel infringements is [5 years]**. An investigation by the EC or NCA interrupts the limitation period. However, an **absolute limitation period of 10 years** applies **[Commission decision: ]** - ordering **termination of infringements** (Art. 7 Cou Reg. 1/2003), - **interim measures** -- urgency due to risk of serious & irreparable damage (Art.8) - accepting **commitments** (Art. 9), - **finding of inapplicability** (Art. 10), - **fines** (Art. 23-24) - **EC's final decisions may be challenged in EU courts** **[Sanctions: ]** - **Primary instrument of prevention** of antitrust violations - **Legal basis**: Cou Reg 1/2003 (art. 23(2)) - Specifics laid out in **Fining Guidelines** - The **amount** depends on nr of factors: **Duration** **+ severity of infringement**: the role of the undertaking in the cartel (instigators and repeat offenders: higher fine) - **Basic amount** related to company's sales + economic importance of market - **Legal maximum 10%** of the total turnover in the preceding business year - A fine may be imposed only in cases of **negligent or intentional violation** of EU competition law. - There are **no criminal sanctions for individuals under EU competition** law **[Leniency program: ]** - **Leniency Notice**: gives cartel members incentive to disclose the existence of cartel + give evidence that enables the EC to initiate or continue the investigation of a cartel. - If a **cartel member is the first to cooperate with EC: it may obtain immunity** from fines subject to certain conditions: - **Cartel members that come in later** may obtain a **substantial reduction of the fine** if they provide the EC with additional information and fulfil a number of additional requirements. - To shorten process the EC may invite cartel members to enter into a **settlement agreement** to reduce the EC's procedural obligations by swiftly terminating the procedure. Cartel members can get a **fine reduction of an additional 10%** as an incentive for entering into a settlement **[Private enforcement:]** - actions by private litigants for cartel damages → **compensation** - CJEU's 2001 *Courage* judgment starting point of Europeanisation of antitrust litigation. - ***Directive 2014/104 on Damages*** harmonized key features of private enforcement actions in the EU - Clear limitation periods (5 y.) - Easier access to evidence - Similarly to the effects of a final infringement decision of the EC, **a final infringement decision of an NCA** constitutes **full proof** of the infringement **before the civil courts in the same MS**. - Rebuttable presumption that cartels cause harm - Receiving full compensation - Joint and several liability of infringers

Use Quizgecko on...
Browser
Browser