Microeconomics Slides Ch 6-8 PDF
Document Details
Uploaded by AppreciatedUranium
University of Bern
Tags
Summary
These notes cover microeconomics topics, including externalities, public goods, and market power. The material is presented in slide format.
Full Transcript
Chapter 6: Externalities Varian, Chapter 24 114 Ch 6.1: Introduction I What is an externality? 115 Ch 6.1: Introduction 116 Ch 6.1: Introduction Definition 6.1 (Externality) An externality is p...
Chapter 6: Externalities Varian, Chapter 24 114 Ch 6.1: Introduction I What is an externality? 115 Ch 6.1: Introduction 116 Ch 6.1: Introduction Definition 6.1 (Externality) An externality is present whenever the well-being of a consumer or the production possibilities of a firm are directly a↵ected by the actions of another agent in the economy. I Definition given in Mas-Colell, Whinston and Green (1995), Ch. 11.B. I When we say “directly” we mean to exclude any e↵ects which are mediated by prices. 117 Ch 6.1: Introduction 118 Ch 6.1: Introduction I If the well-being of a consumer is a↵ected we will speak of a consumption externality. I If the production possibility of a firm is a↵ected we will say it is a production externality. I An externality can be negative or positive. I Smoking in a restaurant and taking a flu vaccine both have a consumption externality. I A chemical plant which pollutes a lake will have a negative production externality on the local fishery. On the other hand, a bee-keeper and an orchard will have positive externality on each other. 119 Ch 6.1: Introduction 120 Ch 6.1: Introduction 121 Ch 6.1: Introduction 122 Ch 6.2: A production externality I A steel mill produces upstream of a fishery. I The steel mill produces steel s from labor according to the production function @ @2 s = (`s ) with > 0, < 0. @`s @`2s I When producing s units of steel, the mill unavoidably produces ⇢(s) units of waste (with @⇢(s) @s > 0), which is expelled into the river. 123 Ch 6.2: A production externality I The fishery produces f units of fish which depends on the amount of labor `f employed and the amount of pollution in the river ⇢. I The production function of the fishery is given by f = (`f , ⇢) with @ @2 @ @2 > 0, < 0, < 0, < 0. @`f @`2f @⇢ @`f @⇢ 124 Ch 6.2: A production externality I The steel mill and the fishery are price takers. I Let p, q and w be the prices of steel, fish and labor. I The profit function of the steel mill is ⇡s (`s |p, w) = p (`s ) w`s while the profit function of the fishery is ⇡f (`f |q, w, `s ) = q (`f , ⇢( (`s ))) w`f. 125 Ch 6.2: A production externality I The steel mill chooses `0s so that @ (`s ) p = w. @`s `s =`0s I Given ⇢0 = ⇢( (`0s )), the fishery chooses `0f so that @ (`f , ⇢0 ) q = w. @`f `f =`0f I The market allocation is then (`0s , `0f ). 126 Ch 6.2: A production externality I This allocation is inefficient. I Suppose the steel mill reduces production by some small amount d`s < 0. The change in its profit is given by " # @ (`s ) d⇡s = p w d`s = 0. `s =`0s @`s `s =`0s | {z } =0 I On the other hand, this reduction in `s impacts the fishery’s profits in a positive way: @ (`f , ⇢) @⇢( ) @ (`s ) d⇡f = q d`s > 0. @⇢ | @{z } @`s |{z} | {z } | {z } 0 127 Ch 6.2: A production externality I The efficient outcome is the solution to max ⇡s + ⇡f. `s ,`f From the FOC with respect to `s we obtain d ! (⇡s + ⇡f ) = 0 d`s @ (`s ) @ (`f , ⇢) @⇢( ) @ (`s ) p w + q =0 @`s @⇢ @ @`s @ (`s ) @ (`f , ⇢) @⇢( ) p+q =w (1) @`s @⇢ @ | {z } `0f and f ⇤ > f 0. 129 Ch 6.3: Solutions I The problem is that the steel mill does not take into account the negative externality that it exerts on the fishery. I Several solutions have been proposed, each with some deficiencies: I Pigovian taxes I Property rights I Missing markets/Coase theorem 130 Ch 6.3: Pigovian taxes Arthur Cecil Pigou (1877-1959) Cambridge (succeeded Alfred Marshall) 131 Ch 6.3: Pigovian taxes I From this perspective, the steel mill faces the wrong price. I p does not include the e↵ect of steel production on the fishery. I If we imposed an appropriate tax on steel production, the steel mill would “internalize” the pollution externality. I The optimal Pigou tax is !✓ ◆ ⇤ ⇤ @ (`⇤f , ⇢) @⇢( ) t = q >0 @⇢ ⇢=⇢⇤ @ = ⇤ 132 Ch 6.3: Pigovian taxes I Now, the profit function of the mill is ⇡s (`s |p, w, t⇤ ) = (p t⇤ ) (`s ) w`s I and the mill chooses `s in order to maximize post-tax profits. I The FOC of the mill is @ (`s ) (p t⇤ ) =w @`s I and it is easy to see that this is the same as the efficiency condition in Eq. (1). 133 Ch 6.3: Pigovian taxes I An example of a Pigou tax is the proposed “carbon tax”. I A problem with Pigou taxes is that it requires a lot of information. I But, optimality is a high standard. Even if we don’t set the tax optimally, a small Pigou tax will improve the outcomes. 134 Ch 6.3: Pigovian taxes 135 Ch 6.3: Missing markets/Coase theorem I From this perspective, the steel mill actually produces two outputs: steel and pollution. I There is no market for pollution. I If there was a market, and the price for pollution was t⇤ , the mill would produce the efficient output. I But the markets for pollution as production externality would likely be thin — there is no reason to expect the competitive price t⇤. I Pollution as consumption externality has attributes of a public good, and the market would likely not provide incentives for pollution reduction. 136 Ch 6.3: Missing markets/Coase theorem I Coase provides a similar argument without having to rely on markets to find the efficient price. I Suppose the mill had the right to pollute. The fisher would have an incentive to pay the mill in order for the mill to reduce the output. I Similarly, suppose the fishery had the right to clean water. The mill would be willing to pay the fishery to the right to pollute. I Coase Theorem: If there are no transaction costs, then independently of the initial allocation of property rights the parties will reach the efficient allocation through voluntary bargaining. 137 Ch 6.3: Missing markets/Coase theorem Ronald Coase (1910-2013) University of Chicago Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics (1991) 138 Ch 6.3: Missing markets/Coase theorem I Coase Theorem seems to solve the problem of externalities, and does so without relying on the state’s knowledge of detailed information (like Pigou). I But, there are problems with this solution too: I If the externality a↵ects many parties, bargaining is difficult due to the free rider problem. If you drive a car, can you negotiate with every person who inhales some of your exhausts? I Also, if the impact of externalities is private knowledge of the agents, then the Coase Theorem breaks — there is actually no mechanism that will lead to the efficient outcome (known as the Myerson-Satterthwaite Theorem). 139 Ch 6.3: Property Rights I Note that if the steel mill and fishery merged, their joint profits would be higher than the sum of their individual profits. I Thus, it would be profitable for one firm to buy the other one. I This will not solve the consumption externalities, or the externalities that are spread out among many firms. 140 Chapter 7: Public goods Varian, Chapter 23 141 Ch 7.1: Introduction I A good is said to be excludable if it is possible to exclude individuals from consuming the good. I An apple is an excludable good. You have to pay the store in order to consume it. I Quiet during the night is not excludable. I A good is said to be nonrival if one individual’s consumption does not diminish the amount available to others. I If I eat an apple, nobody else can eat it. I However, if I sleep well because it is quiet during the night, this does not prevent anyone else from also enjoying the quiet. 142 Ch 7.1: Introduction I If a good is both exludable and rival, we say it is a private good. I An apple is a private good. Until now, we have dealt only with private goods. I If a good is excludable, but it is nonrival, we say it is a club good. I For example, Spotify and Netflix. I A good which is not excludable, but it is rival is called a common good. I For example, fishing in the ocean. I Finally, if a good is not excludable and is nonrival, then we speak of a public good. I A typical example is national defense. 143 Ch 7.1: Introduction I We will focus on discrete public goods. I That is, goods which are either provided (if enough is invested) or not. I A dam to protect against floods. I A sewage treatment plant. I On the other hand we have continuous goods, where investing more provides better, or more, public goods. I For example, national defense. I For simplicity, we consider only the case of two agents. 144 Ch 7.2: Efficient provision of a public good I Suppose there are two agents and two goods, a private good and a public good. I Each agent has some initial endowment of resources !i which can be spent on the private good xi or the public good gi such that xi + gi !i. I Agents have a strongly increasing utility ui (G, xi ). I Public good is discrete and costs c to provide: ( 1 if g1 + g2 c G= (2) 0 if g1 + g2 < c. 145 Ch 7.2: Efficient provision of a public good I When is it Pareto efficient to provide the public good? I An allocation in this setting is a vector of private good consumption and investment in public good (x1 , g1 , x2 , g2 ). An allocation is feasible if: x1 + g 1 + x2 + g 2 !1 + !2. I Suppose that the maximum willingness to pay of agent i for the public good is ri : ui (1, wi ri ) = ui (0, !i ). 146 Ch 7.2: Efficient provision of a public good Proposition 7.1 Consider the allocation xi = !i and gi = 0 for i = 1, 2. It is a Pareto improvement to provide a public good if and only if r1 + r2 > c. 147 Ch 7.3: Market provision of a public good I When goods are private, the First Welfare Theorem tells us that any Walrasian equilibrium will be Pareto efficient. I Will market provision be efficient when goods are public? I Consider the following example: r1 = 100, r2 = 50 and c = 120. According to the result above, it is efficient to provide the public good. I The game is as follows: there is a price for the public good p, and each agent decides whether to pay p or not. The public good is provided only if the sum of paid prices is at least c. 148 Ch 7.3: Market provision of a public good I Depending on p we get the following 3 games. (Why games now, when with private goods we did not have any games?) I First, suppose that p < 60: contributes does not contributes p, p p, 0 does not 0, p 0, 0 149 Ch 7.3: Market provision of a public good I Next, suppose that 60 p < 120: contributes does not contributes 100 p, 50 p p, 0 does not 0, p 0, 0 I Finally, suppose that 120 p: contributes does not contributes 100 p, 50 p 100 p, 50 does not 100, 50 p 0, 0 150 Ch 7.3: Market provision of a public good I Bottom line: the market is likely to under-provide public goods. I We must look for alternative mechanisms for provision of such goods. I An obvious answer is to turn to the government for the provision of such goods. I But how should a government know if the good should be provided? I Maybe the people can vote on whether they want the good or not. 151 Ch 7.3: Voting for a public good 152 Ch 7.3: Voting for a public good I Suppose we have three consumers voting on whether to provide a public good at a cost c = 99. I If the good is provided each consumer pays equally a share of the cost. I If the good is not provided, nobody pays anything. I Suppose consumers vote in favor if and only if their value of receiving the good is greater than the price. I Their reservation prices are r1 = 90, r2 = 30 and r3 = 30. I Thus, it is efficient to provide the public good. 153 Ch 7.3: Voting for a public good I However, if the public good is provided, each consumer will have to pay 99/3 = 33. I Thus, only consumer 1 votes in favor of providing the good and the good is not provided! I In this example, voting leads to uderprovision of the public good, like the market does. 154 Ch 7.3: Voting for a public good I Next, suppose the cost is still 99 but the reservation prices are now r1 = r2 = 40 and r3 = 10. I Now it is not efficient to provide the public good. I But, since the cost is only 33 per person, consumers 1 and 2 vote in favor of the public good. I Now, voting leads to overprovision of the public good! I Clearly, we will need to find a way to incorporate (probably private) information about each agent’s reservation price in both the decision to provide the public good, and in the way the costs are shared. I This (and much more general questions!) is the subject of study of mechanism design, a topic we will explore in the last chapter of this class. 155 Chapter 8: Market Power Jehle and Reny, Chapter 4.2 156 Ch 8.1: Introduction I The results that market outcomes are Pareto efficient depend on the assumption that all agents in the economy act as price takers. I For example, in the Robinson Crusoe economy, we have written the optimization problem of the firm as max ph↵ wh h I However, large firms are aware that they can influence the market price of their products. How does this a↵ect efficiency of equilibria? 157 Ch 8.1: Simple model I Let us consider this question in a simple partial equilibrium model. I Suppose that there is a market for some good, and that the market demands quantity Q if the price of the good is P (Q) = a bQ. I Suppose further that this good can be produced at some marginal cost c. 158 Ch 8.1: Efficient quantity I An outcome is efficient if everyone who values the good more than it costs to produce it, gets the good. I The quantity produced is efficient if P (Q) = c which gives the efficient quantity as a c Q⇤ = b 159 Ch 8.1: Efficient quantity 160 Ch 8.1: Monopoly I Now suppose there is a single firm which can produce the good. That firm chooses the quantity to maximize its profit: max P (q)q cq q or equivalently max (a bq)q cq. q I Solving this yields the monopoly quantity a c qM = 2b 161 Ch 8.1: Monopoly 162 Ch 8.1: Monopoly 163 Ch 8.1: Oligopoly I What would happen if there were N firms choosing quantities simultaneously? ! Cournot model: 0 1 N X max P @ qj Aqi cqi qi j=1 I We can solve this and find that the equilibrium quantity chosen by each firm is 1 a c qN = n+1 b and the total quantity supplied to the market is n a c n QN = = Q⇤ n+1 b n+1 164 Ch 8.1: Oligopoly 165 Ch 8.1: Oligopoly 166 Ch 8.1: Solutions I What should we do about the inefficiencies caused by market power? I Should we make sure there are no large firms with significant market power? 167 Ch 8.1: Solutions I US: - Sherman Act of 1890 - Clayton Act of 1914 I EU: - TFEU Art. 101 and 102 - Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 I Switzerland - Federal Act on Cartels and other Restraints of Competition (Kartellgesetz, 1995) 168